<h2>CHAPTER 7</h2>
<h3>WEALTH AND ITS INDIRECT USES</h3>
<h4>§ I. THE GRADES OF RELATION OF INDIRECT GOODS TO GRATIFICATION</h4>
<div class="sidenote">Technical rank of agents</div>
<p>1. <i>Goods may be ranked according to their technical relation to wants.</i>
The technical rank of goods (sometimes spoken of as the degree of
roundaboutness of the process) signifies the number of steps or
processes that intervene between the agent used and the desired form. If
one wishing the hickory-nut hanging above his head must first pick up a
stick to throw at it, the nut is removed one step from desire. But even
among savages the processes are much more complicated. The Indian with a
crude knife fashions his bow and arrow, fastens the flint and cord which
represent still other processes of industry, and shoots the bird which
satisfies his hunger. In modern conditions the relations are vastly more
complicated; only at the end of a long series do men arrive at the thing
which gratifies their wants.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Time relations of goods to wants</div>
<p>2. <i>Goods may be ranked by their relation to wants in time.</i> The
relation in respect to time is measured by the period that must elapse
before the utility of an agent results in, is converted into,
gratification. No agent or influence intervening, a thing may yet be
removed a long way from<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_47" id="Page_47">[Pg 47]</SPAN></span> gratification. A tree may not be fitted to bear
fruit for ten years to come. Meantime, there are many other possible
uses for the tree: it may be used for fuel, or to make a canoe with
which to catch fish, or to follow some other indirect method of
production. Evidently the technical and time relations of goods are very
different. The number of steps has no necessary relation to the time. A
number of technical steps may be taken in half an hour, or a process of
a single technical step may last a year. In the mechanic arts the
technical relations are of primary significance, but in economics the
time relations are mainly to be considered.</p>
<p>3. <i>Economic goods may be classified as immediately enjoyable goods and
durable agents.</i> Enjoyable goods are goods in a final form, producing
gratification or just ready to give gratification the next moment, as
the cool draft of air made by a fan on a hot day, the cup of coffee
steaming on the table.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Enjoyable goods and durable agents</div>
<p>Many goods of just the same form as the foregoing may not be affording
current gratification (except that afforded by thrift and forethought),
but are kept because later they will gratify a more intense want or
gratify a want better. Apples and potatoes are kept in a cellar so that
their use is distributed throughout the winter; cider and wine are kept
till they get a quality that appeals more to the palate. Coal, wood, and
stocks of goods, are thus kept in the form of enjoyable goods, destined
to be physically destroyed when at length they yield a gratification.
Evidently they must be storing up meantime a certain additional utility,
for otherwise there would be no reason why they should be kept for the
future. Such goods as these are sometimes called unripened consumption
goods, but until ripened they bear in part the character of durable
agents.</p>
<p>Abiding sources of economic enjoyments are called durable agents. The
inhabited house is a source of continued gratification in each moment's
shelter it affords; but, further, it is the durable source of a series
of future uses, as yet unripened.<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_48" id="Page_48">[Pg 48]</SPAN></span> The hammer, the hoe, the tree, the
field may all be considered as agents to secure consumption goods. Some
of these are but one step removed from direct gratification, as the hoe
helping the gardener to get food for his own use. Other agents are bound
by many technical links to the ultimate gratification.</p>
<div class="sidenote">Degrees of durableness</div>
<p>4. <i>This classification of goods is abstract, in that it is a
classification, not of concrete goods, but of qualities shared in some
degree by nearly all goods.</i> Most goods unite in some degree both
characters, but in varying measure. This is, therefore, a continuity
classification, the varying classes of goods grading from those whose
durableness is zero (just at the moment of consumption) to those most
durable, which yield an endless series of uses or products. Yet the
classification is practical, corresponding as it does with thoughts
which men have in the use of goods. By repairs and other methods goods
become, and are looked upon as, durable sources of a series of uses.</p>
<p>It is to be noted further that the enjoyable goods pass over into
psychic income, that is, they are the stream of objective utilities that
is each moment detaching itself as income from the great mass of wealth.
The durable goods are those utilities which for the time remain, not yet
ripened or ready to be converted into psychic income.</p>
<h4>§ II. CONDITIONS OF ECONOMIC WEALTH</h4>
<div class="sidenote">Income as affected by climatic conditions</div>
<p>1. <i>The bounty and variety of the natural supply of indirect goods in
the material world are the prime conditions of a bountiful income to
society.</i> The effect of climate on the supply of goods available for man
is complex. Climate is itself a direct source of gratification. As
temperature must be adjusted to man's need, climate satisfies wants
directly. Health, energy, the beauty of noonday woods and of sunlit
clouds are conditioned on the favor of nature. Climate affects, further,
the supply of material economic goods. All<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_49" id="Page_49">[Pg 49]</SPAN></span> the earlier civilizations
arose in warmer countries. But, after man had gained a certain mastery
over the obstacles of nature, he was able to soften the harsher features
of climate, and with better shelter and clothing, with better stocks of
winter food and fuel, the more favorable features of the temperate zone
could be utilized. So civilization moved northward from Egypt and India
to Greece and Rome, to northern Europe and America.</p>
<div class="sidenote">By natural resources</div>
<p>Soil conditions for vegetable life determine first the amount and kind
of animal life. Animal life from one point of view is a parasite, living
on the vegetable; it is only the vegetable that has power to assimilate
most inorganic compounds. Water being a need of plant life, the amount
of rainfall is one of the most important conditions of industry. Man,
therefore, depends on the resources of the soil directly or indirectly;
a fertile soil furnishes him either directly a supply of vegetable food,
or indirectly a supply of animal food.</p>
<p>Natural supplies of metals, of coal, and of timber are important
consumption goods, but they are also indirectly the condition for a vast
variety of other goods. The industry that could exist without iron,
copper, and coal would be of a very low grade.</p>
<div class="sidenote">By flora and fauna</div>
<p>The variety of flora and fauna, and their fitness for man's needs,
largely condition the possible production. If, in the course of
evolution, it had chanced that wheat and corn, the horse and the cow,
had been crowded out in the struggle for existence, we should have had a
very different civilization. The possibilities of civilization in Peru,
and those of all the Indians on the American continent, were limited for
lack of domestic animals. Animals that are fit for domestication are a
necessary intermediate agent by aid of which man can appropriate and
turn to his use the fertile qualities of the soil.</p>
<p>Not content with the material world about him, even when it is at its
best, man alters it in many ways. He enriches the soil, improves the
varieties of animals, he even in some<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_50" id="Page_50">[Pg 50]</SPAN></span> slight degree affects the
climate, and by the use of a multitude of artificial bits of matter
called tools, works profound changes in the world in which he lives.</p>
<div class="sidenote">By motion and energy</div>
<p>2. <i>A large part of the utility of goods is conditioned on motion and
energy.</i> It has been said that man's power in production is limited to
moving things. The outer world is to man the sole source of motive
forces. He can bring things together and they produce the result.
Further, it may be said that nearly every kind of utility is conditioned
on motion. It is man's aim to secure a constant inflow of goods. To
secure this either he must move to get the goods, or he must cause goods
to move toward him.</p>
<p>The law of "conservation of energy" helps to explain economic action;
the supply of energy in the universe cannot be increased or diminished,
but may take on new forms. So a limited supply in man's control may take
on various forms and so have different effects on gratifications. One
and the same source of energy may be converted into the different forms
of heat, light, motion, electricity, etc. But there must be some source.
Man's desire is directed to getting force at the right place and in the
right degree. If light or heat is too intense, it causes pain; the glare
of the sun blinds instead of giving keener vision. A moderate force
applied to any of the senses gives the maximum clearness or pleasure.
Man is constantly endeavoring to secure forces from the outer world and
to adjust motion so that it will directly or indirectly best serve his
purposes.</p>
<div class="sidenote">By food, animals, and fuel</div>
<p>3. <i>Among the main sources of power used by men are food, domestic
animals, and fuel.</i> In eating food man stores up force in his own body.
When he draws the bow he puts force into it to lie latent until
liberated at the right moment. There must be a source of energy likewise
that mental action may go on, and the power of sunbeams, stored for a
time in food, is liberated in the processes of thought.</p>
<p>This first natural mode of liberating energy within their own bodies
does not satisfy the growing needs and aims of<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_51" id="Page_51">[Pg 51]</SPAN></span> men. Such a mode is
"labor," which becomes at times painful and distasteful. In the earliest
societies known, some sorts of domestic animals are found supplementing
man's efforts and acting upon the material world to alter it for man.
The dog joining in the chase guards his master's safety, and helps to
bear his burdens. The draft-beast in the field turns the heavy soil, and
aids in the final harvest. The trained elephant does the work of twenty
men piling logs, loading ships, or carrying burdens.</p>
<p>Man further increases his control over the material world by making
other men do his bidding. Domestic slavery, where wife or child serves
the father of the family, or chattel slavery, where the vanquished toils
for the victor, are all but universal in early communities. Such a
method of increasing one's control over the forces of the world requires
only superior strength, no special intelligence in mechanics, and is
thus one of the first crude devices in a primitive civilization.</p>
<p>Fuel has been, up to the present time, perhaps the most important source
of energy. Fire in the hands of savage man gave him dominion over the
forests and over the metals. In this age of steam the liberation of the
energy of the sun, stored up in coal in ages past, is still the
indispensable condition of our developed industry.</p>
<div class="sidenote">By the energy in wind and flowing water</div>
<p>4. <i>The greatest and most exhaustless reservoirs of power for man's use
are in wind and water.</i> While the supply of fuel is being used at a
progressive rate and will soon approach exhaustion, there are elsewhere
exhaustless stores of energy awaiting man's command. To make use of the
wind for sailing a boat, only the simplest arrangements are needed; a
windmill fixed at one place requires more ingenuity and machinery. The
energy of the wind is derived from the sun and will last until the sun
loses its heat. If some means can be found for equalizing the flow and
for storing the power of the wind, it may yet become a great agency of
industry. The force of falling water, long used in a petty<span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_52" id="Page_52">[Pg 52]</SPAN></span> way by the
old water-mills, is just beginning to be employed on a large scale at
such points as Niagara. Where fuel is high, as on the Pacific coast,
wave motors have been successfully used in a small way, but wave motion
is too irregular to serve well the needs for power. But the constant
motion of the tides offers, at some favored points, a source of power
that will remain as long as the earth revolves upon its axis.</p>
<div class="sidenote">By the intelligent utilization of all these agencies</div>
<p>5. <i>Man studies and compares the durable goods that give him command
over enjoyable goods, and attaches value to them.</i> Thus energy is found
dissipating itself throughout the world in ways useless to man, and in
places where it cannot serve his purposes. As man grows in power of
control over nature, he seeks to apply these forces in forms and at
places he has selected. If he can arm himself with the energies of mine
and torrent, he can react with giant strength on the material world. He
ceases to accept passively its conditions, and to live on its grudging
gifts; he becomes its fashioner, in a sense its creator. His
intelligence and his wants are most important factors determining what
the form of the physical world about him shall be.</p>
<p>But all the efforts of men in the most developed economy cannot make to
disappear the differences in the quality of goods and agents. Desirable
goods to consume are limited in quantity, and they vary in quality;
hence they have value and some higher than others. Likewise, durable
material agents and sources of power are limited in number and vary in
convenience of location and efficiency. As men seek to gratify their
desires, they attach importance to these agents of power. Each is valued
for its service or its series of services. When anything is seen to
contain a series of uses, it becomes a rent-bearer, and the economic
problem of rent arises, one step more complex than the problem of
valuing simple consumption goods.</p>
<hr class="chap" />
<p><span class="pagenum"><SPAN name="Page_53" id="Page_53">[Pg 53]</SPAN></span></p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />