<p>PUBLIUS <SPAN name="link2H_4_0052" id="link2H_4_0052"></SPAN></p>
<h2> FEDERALIST No. 52. The House of Representatives </h2>
<h3> From the New York Packet. Friday, February 8, 1788. </h3>
<p>MADISON</p>
<p>To the People of the State of New York:</p>
<p>FROM the more general inquiries pursued in the four last papers, I pass on
to a more particular examination of the several parts of the government. I
shall begin with the House of Representatives.</p>
<p>The first view to be taken of this part of the government relates to the
qualifications of the electors and the elected. Those of the former are to
be the same with those of the electors of the most numerous branch of the
State legislatures. The definition of the right of suffrage is very justly
regarded as a fundamental article of republican government. It was
incumbent on the convention, therefore, to define and establish this right
in the Constitution. To have left it open for the occasional regulation of
the Congress, would have been improper for the reason just mentioned. To
have submitted it to the legislative discretion of the States, would have
been improper for the same reason; and for the additional reason that it
would have rendered too dependent on the State governments that branch of
the federal government which ought to be dependent on the people alone. To
have reduced the different qualifications in the different States to one
uniform rule, would probably have been as dissatisfactory to some of the
States as it would have been difficult to the convention. The provision
made by the convention appears, therefore, to be the best that lay within
their option. It must be satisfactory to every State, because it is
conformable to the standard already established, or which may be
established, by the State itself. It will be safe to the United States,
because, being fixed by the State constitutions, it is not alterable by
the State governments, and it cannot be feared that the people of the
States will alter this part of their constitutions in such a manner as to
abridge the rights secured to them by the federal Constitution.</p>
<p>The qualifications of the elected, being less carefully and properly
defined by the State constitutions, and being at the same time more
susceptible of uniformity, have been very properly considered and
regulated by the convention. A representative of the United States must be
of the age of twenty-five years; must have been seven years a citizen of
the United States; must, at the time of his election, be an inhabitant of
the State he is to represent; and, during the time of his service, must be
in no office under the United States. Under these reasonable limitations,
the door of this part of the federal government is open to merit of every
description, whether native or adoptive, whether young or old, and without
regard to poverty or wealth, or to any particular profession of religious
faith.</p>
<p>The term for which the representatives are to be elected falls under a
second view which may be taken of this branch. In order to decide on the
propriety of this article, two questions must be considered: first,
whether biennial elections will, in this case, be safe; secondly, whether
they be necessary or useful.</p>
<p>First. As it is essential to liberty that the government in general should
have a common interest with the people, so it is particularly essential
that the branch of it under consideration should have an immediate
dependence on, and an intimate sympathy with, the people. Frequent
elections are unquestionably the only policy by which this dependence and
sympathy can be effectually secured. But what particular degree of
frequency may be absolutely necessary for the purpose, does not appear to
be susceptible of any precise calculation, and must depend on a variety of
circumstances with which it may be connected. Let us consult experience,
the guide that ought always to be followed whenever it can be found.</p>
<p>The scheme of representation, as a substitute for a meeting of the
citizens in person, being at most but very imperfectly known to ancient
polity, it is in more modern times only that we are to expect instructive
examples. And even here, in order to avoid a research too vague and
diffusive, it will be proper to confine ourselves to the few examples
which are best known, and which bear the greatest analogy to our
particular case. The first to which this character ought to be applied, is
the House of Commons in Great Britain. The history of this branch of the
English Constitution, anterior to the date of Magna Charta, is too obscure
to yield instruction. The very existence of it has been made a question
among political antiquaries. The earliest records of subsequent date prove
that parliaments were to SIT only every year; not that they were to be
ELECTED every year. And even these annual sessions were left so much at
the discretion of the monarch, that, under various pretexts, very long and
dangerous intermissions were often contrived by royal ambition. To remedy
this grievance, it was provided by a statute in the reign of Charles II,
that the intermissions should not be protracted beyond a period of three
years. On the accession of William III, when a revolution took place in
the government, the subject was still more seriously resumed, and it was
declared to be among the fundamental rights of the people that parliaments
ought to be held FREQUENTLY. By another statute, which passed a few years
later in the same reign, the term "frequently," which had alluded to the
triennial period settled in the time of Charles II, is reduced to a
precise meaning, it being expressly enacted that a new parliament shall be
called within three years after the termination of the former. The last
change, from three to seven years, is well known to have been introduced
pretty early in the present century, under on alarm for the Hanoverian
succession. From these facts it appears that the greatest frequency of
elections which has been deemed necessary in that kingdom, for binding the
representatives to their constituents, does not exceed a triennial return
of them. And if we may argue from the degree of liberty retained even
under septennial elections, and all the other vicious ingredients in the
parliamentary constitution, we cannot doubt that a reduction of the period
from seven to three years, with the other necessary reforms, would so far
extend the influence of the people over their representatives as to
satisfy us that biennial elections, under the federal system, cannot
possibly be dangerous to the requisite dependence of the House of
Representatives on their constituents.</p>
<p>Elections in Ireland, till of late, were regulated entirely by the
discretion of the crown, and were seldom repeated, except on the accession
of a new prince, or some other contingent event. The parliament which
commenced with George II. was continued throughout his whole reign, a
period of about thirty-five years. The only dependence of the
representatives on the people consisted in the right of the latter to
supply occasional vacancies by the election of new members, and in the
chance of some event which might produce a general new election. The
ability also of the Irish parliament to maintain the rights of their
constituents, so far as the disposition might exist, was extremely
shackled by the control of the crown over the subjects of their
deliberation. Of late these shackles, if I mistake not, have been broken;
and octennial parliaments have besides been established. What effect may
be produced by this partial reform, must be left to further experience.
The example of Ireland, from this view of it, can throw but little light
on the subject. As far as we can draw any conclusion from it, it must be
that if the people of that country have been able under all these
disadvantages to retain any liberty whatever, the advantage of biennial
elections would secure to them every degree of liberty, which might depend
on a due connection between their representatives and themselves.</p>
<p>Let us bring our inquiries nearer home. The example of these States, when
British colonies, claims particular attention, at the same time that it is
so well known as to require little to be said on it. The principle of
representation, in one branch of the legislature at least, was established
in all of them. But the periods of election were different. They varied
from one to seven years. Have we any reason to infer, from the spirit and
conduct of the representatives of the people, prior to the Revolution,
that biennial elections would have been dangerous to the public liberties?
The spirit which everywhere displayed itself at the commencement of the
struggle, and which vanquished the obstacles to independence, is the best
of proofs that a sufficient portion of liberty had been everywhere enjoyed
to inspire both a sense of its worth and a zeal for its proper enlargement
This remark holds good, as well with regard to the then colonies whose
elections were least frequent, as to those whose elections were most
frequent Virginia was the colony which stood first in resisting the
parliamentary usurpations of Great Britain; it was the first also in
espousing, by public act, the resolution of independence. In Virginia,
nevertheless, if I have not been misinformed, elections under the former
government were septennial. This particular example is brought into view,
not as a proof of any peculiar merit, for the priority in those instances
was probably accidental; and still less of any advantage in SEPTENNIAL
elections, for when compared with a greater frequency they are
inadmissible; but merely as a proof, and I conceive it to be a very
substantial proof, that the liberties of the people can be in no danger
from BIENNIAL elections.</p>
<p>The conclusion resulting from these examples will be not a little
strengthened by recollecting three circumstances. The first is, that the
federal legislature will possess a part only of that supreme legislative
authority which is vested completely in the British Parliament; and which,
with a few exceptions, was exercised by the colonial assemblies and the
Irish legislature. It is a received and well-founded maxim, that where no
other circumstances affect the case, the greater the power is, the shorter
ought to be its duration; and, conversely, the smaller the power, the more
safely may its duration be protracted. In the second place, it has, on
another occasion, been shown that the federal legislature will not only be
restrained by its dependence on its people, as other legislative bodies
are, but that it will be, moreover, watched and controlled by the several
collateral legislatures, which other legislative bodies are not. And in
the third place, no comparison can be made between the means that will be
possessed by the more permanent branches of the federal government for
seducing, if they should be disposed to seduce, the House of
Representatives from their duty to the people, and the means of influence
over the popular branch possessed by the other branches of the government
above cited. With less power, therefore, to abuse, the federal
representatives can be less tempted on one side, and will be doubly
watched on the other.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />