<h2><SPAN name="chap14"></SPAN>Chapter XIV</h2>
<p>The development of Cowperwood as Cowperwood & Co. following his arresting
bond venture, finally brought him into relationship with one man who was to
play an important part in his life, morally, financially, and in other ways.
This was George W. Stener, the new city treasurer-elect, who, to begin with,
was a puppet in the hands of other men, but who, also in spite of this fact,
became a personage of considerable importance, for the simple reason that he
was weak. Stener had been engaged in the real estate and insurance business in
a small way before he was made city treasurer. He was one of those men, of whom
there are so many thousands in every large community, with no breadth of
vision, no real subtlety, no craft, no great skill in anything. You would never
hear a new idea emanating from Stener. He never had one in his life. On the
other hand, he was not a bad fellow. He had a stodgy, dusty, commonplace look
to him which was more a matter of mind than of body. His eye was of vague
gray-blue; his hair a dusty light-brown and thin. His mouth—there was
nothing impressive there. He was quite tall, nearly six feet, with moderately
broad shoulders, but his figure was anything but shapely. He seemed to stoop a
little, his stomach was the least bit protuberant, and he talked
commonplaces—the small change of newspaper and street and business
gossip. People liked him in his own neighborhood. He was thought to be honest
and kindly; and he was, as far as he knew. His wife and four children were as
average and insignificant as the wives and children of such men usually are.</p>
<p>Just the same, and in spite of, or perhaps, politically speaking, because of
all this, George W. Stener was brought into temporary public notice by certain
political methods which had existed in Philadelphia practically unmodified for
the previous half hundred years. First, because he was of the same political
faith as the dominant local political party, he had become known to the local
councilman and ward-leader of his ward as a faithful soul—one useful in
the matter of drumming up votes. And next—although absolutely without
value as a speaker, for he had no ideas—you could send him from door to
door, asking the grocer and the blacksmith and the butcher how he felt about
things and he would make friends, and in the long run predict fairly accurately
the probable vote. Furthermore, you could dole him out a few platitudes and he
would repeat them. The Republican party, which was the new-born party then, but
dominant in Philadelphia, needed your vote; it was necessary to keep the
rascally Democrats out—he could scarcely have said why. They had been for
slavery. They were for free trade. It never once occurred to him that these
things had nothing to do with the local executive and financial administration
of Philadelphia. Supposing they didn’t? What of it?</p>
<p>In Philadelphia at this time a certain United States Senator, one Mark Simpson,
together with Edward Malia Butler and Henry A. Mollenhauer, a rich coal dealer
and investor, were supposed to, and did, control jointly the political destiny
of the city. They had representatives, benchmen, spies, tools—a great
company. Among them was this same Stener—a minute cog in the silent
machinery of their affairs.</p>
<p>In scarcely any other city save this, where the inhabitants were of a deadly
average in so far as being commonplace was concerned, could such a man as
Stener have been elected city treasurer. The rank and file did not, except in
rare instances, make up their political program. An inside ring had this matter
in charge. Certain positions were allotted to such and such men or to such and
such factions of the party for such and such services rendered—but who
does not know politics?</p>
<p>In due course of time, therefore, George W. Stener had become persona grata to
Edward Strobik, a quondam councilman who afterward became ward leader and still
later president of council, and who, in private life was a stone-dealer and
owner of a brickyard. Strobik was a benchman of Henry A. Mollenhauer, the
hardest and coldest of all three of the political leaders. The latter had
things to get from council, and Strobik was his tool. He had Stener elected;
and because he was faithful in voting as he was told the latter was later made
an assistant superintendent of the highways department.</p>
<p>Here he came under the eyes of Edward Malia Butler, and was slightly useful to
him. Then the central political committee, with Butler in charge, decided that
some nice, docile man who would at the same time be absolutely faithful was
needed for city treasurer, and Stener was put on the ticket. He knew little of
finance, but was an excellent bookkeeper; and, anyhow, was not corporation
counsel Regan, another political tool of this great triumvirate, there to
advise him at all times? He was. It was a very simple matter. Being put on the
ticket was equivalent to being elected, and so, after a few weeks of
exceedingly trying platform experiences, in which he had stammered through
platitudinous declarations that the city needed to be honestly administered, he
was inducted into office; and there you were.</p>
<p>Now it wouldn’t have made so much difference what George W.
Stener’s executive and financial qualifications for the position were,
but at this time the city of Philadelphia was still hobbling along under
perhaps as evil a financial system, or lack of it, as any city ever
endured—the assessor and the treasurer being allowed to collect and hold
moneys belonging to the city, outside of the city’s private vaults, and
that without any demand on the part of anybody that the same be invested by
them at interest for the city’s benefit. Rather, all they were expected
to do, apparently, was to restore the principal and that which was with them
when they entered or left office. It was not understood or publicly demanded
that the moneys so collected, or drawn from any source, be maintained intact in
the vaults of the city treasury. They could be loaned out, deposited in banks
or used to further private interests of any one, so long as the principal was
returned, and no one was the wiser. Of course, this theory of finance was not
publicly sanctioned, but it was known politically and journalistically, and in
high finance. How were you to stop it?</p>
<p>Cowperwood, in approaching Edward Malia Butler, had been unconsciously let in
on this atmosphere of erratic and unsatisfactory speculation without really
knowing it. When he had left the office of Tighe & Co., seven years before,
it was with the idea that henceforth and forever he would have nothing to do
with the stock-brokerage proposition; but now behold him back in it again, with
more vim than he had ever displayed, for now he was working for himself, the
firm of Cowperwood & Co., and he was eager to satisfy the world of new and
powerful individuals who by degrees were drifting to him. All had a little
money. All had tips, and they wanted him to carry certain lines of stock on
margin for them, because he was known to other political men, and because he
was safe. And this was true. He was not, or at least up to this time had not
been, a speculator or a gambler on his own account. In fact he often soothed
himself with the thought that in all these years he had never gambled for
himself, but had always acted strictly for others instead. But now here was
George W. Stener with a proposition which was not quite the same thing as
stock-gambling, and yet it was.</p>
<p>During a long period of years preceding the Civil War, and through it, let it
here be explained and remembered, the city of Philadelphia had been in the
habit, as a corporation, when there were no available funds in the treasury, of
issuing what were known as city warrants, which were nothing more than notes or
I.O.U.’s bearing six per cent. interest, and payable sometimes in thirty
days, sometimes in three, sometimes in six months—all depending on the
amount and how soon the city treasurer thought there would be sufficient money
in the treasury to take them up and cancel them. Small tradesmen and large
contractors were frequently paid in this way; the small tradesman who sold
supplies to the city institutions, for instance, being compelled to discount
his notes at the bank, if he needed ready money, usually for ninety cents on
the dollar, while the large contractor could afford to hold his and wait. It
can readily be seen that this might well work to the disadvantage of the small
dealer and merchant, and yet prove quite a fine thing for a large contractor or
note-broker, for the city was sure to pay the warrants at some time, and six
per cent. interest was a fat rate, considering the absolute security. A banker
or broker who gathered up these things from small tradesmen at ninety cents on
the dollar made a fine thing of it all around if he could wait.</p>
<p>Originally, in all probability, there was no intention on the part of the city
treasurer to do any one an injustice, and it is likely that there really were
no funds to pay with at the time. However that may have been, there was later
no excuse for issuing the warrants, seeing that the city might easily have been
managed much more economically. But these warrants, as can readily be imagined,
had come to be a fine source of profit for note-brokers, bankers, political
financiers, and inside political manipulators generally and so they remained a
part of the city’s fiscal policy.</p>
<p>There was just one drawback to all this. In order to get the full advantage of
this condition the large banker holding them must be an “inside
banker,” one close to the political forces of the city, for if he was not
and needed money and he carried his warrants to the city treasurer, he would
find that he could not get cash for them. But if he transferred them to some
banker or note-broker who was close to the political force of the city, it was
quite another matter. The treasury would find means to pay. Or, if so desired
by the note-broker or banker—the right one—notes which were
intended to be met in three months, and should have been settled at that time,
were extended to run on years and years, drawing interest at six per cent. even
when the city had ample funds to meet them. Yet this meant, of course, an
illegal interest drain on the city, but that was all right also. “No
funds” could cover that. The general public did not know. It could not
find out. The newspapers were not at all vigilant, being pro-political. There
were no persistent, enthusiastic reformers who obtained any political credence.
During the war, warrants outstanding in this manner arose in amount to much
over two million dollars, all drawing six per cent. interest, but then, of
course, it began to get a little scandalous. Besides, at least some of the
investors began to want their money back.</p>
<p>In order, therefore, to clear up this outstanding indebtedness and make
everything shipshape again, it was decided that the city must issue a loan, say
for two million dollars—no need to be exact about the amount. And this
loan must take the shape of interest-bearing certificates of a par value of one
hundred dollars, redeemable in six, twelve, or eighteen months, as the case may
be. These certificates of loan were then ostensibly to be sold in the open
market, a sinking-fund set aside for their redemption, and the money so
obtained used to take up the long-outstanding warrants which were now such a
subject of public comment.</p>
<p>It is obvious that this was merely a case of robbing Peter to pay Paul. There
was no real clearing up of the outstanding debt. It was the intention of the
schemers to make it possible for the financial politicians on the inside to
reap the same old harvest by allowing the certificates to be sold to the right
parties for ninety or less, setting up the claim that there was no market for
them, the credit of the city being bad. To a certain extent this was true. The
war was just over. Money was high. Investors could get more than six per cent.
elsewhere unless the loan was sold at ninety. But there were a few watchful
politicians not in the administration, and some newspapers and non-political
financiers who, because of the high strain of patriotism existing at the time,
insisted that the loan should be sold at par. Therefore a clause to that effect
had to be inserted in the enabling ordinance.</p>
<p>This, as one might readily see, destroyed the politicians’ little scheme
to get this loan at ninety. Nevertheless since they desired that the money tied
up in the old warrants and now not redeemable because of lack of funds should
be paid them, the only way this could be done would be to have some broker who
knew the subtleties of the stock market handle this new city loan on
’change in such a way that it would be made to seem worth one hundred and
to be sold to outsiders at that figure. Afterward, if, as it was certain to do,
it fell below that, the politicians could buy as much of it as they pleased,
and eventually have the city redeem it at par.</p>
<p>George W. Stener, entering as city treasurer at this time, and bringing no
special financial intelligence to the proposition, was really troubled. Henry
A. Mollenhauer, one of the men who had gathered up a large amount of the old
city warrants, and who now wanted his money, in order to invest it in bonanza
offers in the West, called on Stener, and also on the mayor. He with Simpson
and Butler made up the Big Three.</p>
<p>“I think something ought to be done about these warrants that are
outstanding,” he explained. “I am carrying a large amount of them,
and there are others. We have helped the city a long time by saying nothing;
but now I think that something ought to be done. Mr. Butler and Mr. Simpson
feel the same way. Couldn’t these new loan certificates be listed on the
stock exchange and the money raised that way? Some clever broker could bring
them to par.”</p>
<p>Stener was greatly flattered by the visit from Mollenhauer. Rarely did he
trouble to put in a personal appearance, and then only for the weight and
effect his presence would have. He called on the mayor and the president of
council, much as he called on Stener, with a lofty, distant, inscrutable air.
They were as office-boys to him.</p>
<p>In order to understand exactly the motive for Mollenhauer’s interest in
Stener, and the significance of this visit and Stener’s subsequent action
in regard to it, it will be necessary to scan the political horizon for some
little distance back. Although George W. Stener was in a way a political
henchman and appointee of Mollenhauer’s, the latter was only vaguely
acquainted with him. He had seen him before; knew of him; had agreed that his
name should be put on the local slate largely because he had been assured by
those who were closest to him and who did his bidding that Stener was
“all right,” that he would do as he was told, that he would cause
no one any trouble, etc. In fact, during several previous administrations,
Mollenhauer had maintained a subsurface connection with the treasury, but never
so close a one as could easily be traced. He was too conspicuous a man
politically and financially for that. But he was not above a plan, in which
Simpson if not Butler shared, of using political and commercial stool-pigeons
to bleed the city treasury as much as possible without creating a scandal. In
fact, for some years previous to this, various agents had already been
employed—Edward Strobik, president of council, Asa Conklin, the then
incumbent of the mayor’s chair, Thomas Wycroft, alderman, Jacob Harmon,
alderman, and others—to organize dummy companies under various names,
whose business it was to deal in those things which the city
needed—lumber, stone, steel, iron, cement—a long list—and of
course, always at a fat profit to those ultimately behind the dummy companies,
so organized. It saved the city the trouble of looking far and wide for honest
and reasonable dealers.</p>
<p>Since the action of at least three of these dummies will have something to do
with the development of Cowperwood’s story, they may be briefly
described. Edward Strobik, the chief of them, and the one most useful to
Mollenhauer, in a minor way, was a very spry person of about thirty-five at
this time—lean and somewhat forceful, with black hair, black eyes, and an
inordinately large black mustache. He was dapper, inclined to noticeable
clothing—a pair of striped trousers, a white vest, a black cutaway coat
and a high silk hat. His markedly ornamental shoes were always polished to
perfection, and his immaculate appearance gave him the nickname of “The
Dude” among some. Nevertheless he was quite able on a small scale, and
was well liked by many.</p>
<p>His two closest associates, Messrs. Thomas Wycroft and Jacob Harmon, were
rather less attractive and less brilliant. Jacob Harmon was a thick wit
socially, but no fool financially. He was big and rather doleful to look upon,
with sandy brown hair and brown eyes, but fairly intelligent, and absolutely
willing to approve anything which was not too broad in its crookedness and
which would afford him sufficient protection to keep him out of the clutches of
the law. He was really not so cunning as dull and anxious to get along.</p>
<p>Thomas Wycroft, the last of this useful but minor triumvirate, was a tall, lean
man, candle-waxy, hollow-eyed, gaunt of face, pathetic to look at physically,
but shrewd. He was an iron-molder by trade and had gotten into politics much as
Stener had—because he was useful; and he had managed to make some
money—via this triumvirate of which Strobik was the ringleader, and which
was engaged in various peculiar businesses which will now be indicated.</p>
<p>The companies which these several henchmen had organized under previous
administrations, and for Mollenhauer, dealt in meat, building material,
lamp-posts, highway supplies, anything you will, which the city departments or
its institutions needed. A city contract once awarded was irrevocable, but
certain councilmen had to be fixed in advance and it took money to do that. The
company so organized need not actually slaughter any cattle or mold lamp-posts.
All it had to do was to organize to do that, obtain a charter, secure a
contract for supplying such material to the city from the city council (which
Strobik, Harmon, and Wycroft would attend to), and then sublet this to some
actual beef-slaughterer or iron-founder, who would supply the material and
allow them to pocket their profit which in turn was divided or paid for to
Mollenhauer and Simpson in the form of political donations to clubs or
organizations. It was so easy and in a way so legitimate. The particular
beef-slaughterer or iron-founder thus favored could not hope of his own ability
thus to obtain a contract. Stener, or whoever was in charge of the city
treasury at the time, for his services in loaning money at a low rate of
interest to be used as surety for the proper performance of contract, and to
aid in some instances the beef-killer or iron-founder to carry out his end, was
to be allowed not only the one or two per cent. which he might pocket (other
treasurers had), but a fair proportion of the profits. A complacent,
confidential chief clerk who was all right would be recommended to him. It did
not concern Stener that Strobik, Harmon, and Wycroft, acting for Mollenhauer,
were incidentally planning to use a little of the money loaned for purposes
quite outside those indicated. It was his business to loan it.</p>
<p>However, to be going on. Some time before he was even nominated, Stener had
learned from Strobik, who, by the way, was one of his sureties as treasurer
(which suretyship was against the law, as were those of Councilmen Wycroft and
Harmon, the law of Pennsylvania stipulating that one political servant might
not become surety for another), that those who had brought about this
nomination and election would by no means ask him to do anything which was not
perfectly legal, but that he must be complacent and not stand in the way of big
municipal perquisites nor bite the hands that fed him. It was also made
perfectly plain to him, that once he was well in office a little money for
himself was to be made. As has been indicated, he had always been a poor man.
He had seen all those who had dabbled in politics to any extent about him
heretofore do very well financially indeed, while he pegged along as an
insurance and real-estate agent. He had worked hard as a small political
henchman. Other politicians were building themselves nice homes in newer
portions of the city. They were going off to New York or Harrisburg or
Washington on jaunting parties. They were seen in happy converse at road-houses
or country hotels in season with their wives or their women favorites, and he
was not, as yet, of this happy throng. Naturally now that he was promised
something, he was interested and compliant. What might he not get?</p>
<p>When it came to this visit from Mollenhauer, with its suggestion in regard to
bringing city loan to par, although it bore no obvious relation to
Mollenhauer’s subsurface connection with Stener, through Strobik and the
others, Stener did definitely recognize his own political
subservience—his master’s stentorian voice—and immediately
thereafter hurried to Strobik for information.</p>
<p>“Just what would you do about this?” he asked of Strobik, who knew
of Mollenhauer’s visit before Stener told him, and was waiting for Stener
to speak to him. “Mr. Mollenhauer talks about having this new loan listed
on ’change and brought to par so that it will sell for one
hundred.”</p>
<p>Neither Strobik, Harmon, nor Wycroft knew how the certificates of city loan,
which were worth only ninety on the open market, were to be made to sell for
one hundred on ’change, but Mollenhauer’s secretary, one Abner
Sengstack, had suggested to Strobik that, since Butler was dealing with young
Cowperwood and Mollenhauer did not care particularly for his private broker in
this instance, it might be as well to try Cowperwood.</p>
<p>So it was that Cowperwood was called to Stener’s office. And once there,
and not as yet recognizing either the hand of Mollenhauer or Simpson in this,
merely looked at the peculiarly shambling, heavy-cheeked, middle-class man
before him without either interest or sympathy, realizing at once that he had a
financial baby to deal with. If he could act as adviser to this man—be
his sole counsel for four years!</p>
<p>“How do you do, Mr. Stener?” he said in his soft, ingratiating
voice, as the latter held out his hand. “I am glad to meet you. I have
heard of you before, of course.”</p>
<p>Stener was long in explaining to Cowperwood just what his difficulty was. He
went at it in a clumsy fashion, stumbling through the difficulties of the
situation he was suffered to meet.</p>
<p>“The main thing, as I see it, is to make these certificates sell at par.
I can issue them in any sized lots you like, and as often as you like. I want
to get enough now to clear away two hundred thousand dollars’ worth of
the outstanding warrants, and as much more as I can get later.”</p>
<p>Cowperwood felt like a physician feeling a patient’s pulse—a
patient who is really not sick at all but the reassurance of whom means a fat
fee. The abstrusities of the stock exchange were as his A B C’s to him.
He knew if he could have this loan put in his hands—all of it, if he
could have the fact kept dark that he was acting for the city, and that if
Stener would allow him to buy as a “bull” for the sinking-fund
while selling judiciously for a rise, he could do wonders even with a big
issue. He had to have all of it, though, in order that he might have agents
under him. Looming up in his mind was a scheme whereby he could make a lot of
the unwary speculators about ’change go short of this stock or loan under
the impression, of course, that it was scattered freely in various
persons’ hands, and that they could buy as much of it as they wanted.
Then they would wake to find that they could not get it; that he had it all.
Only he would not risk his secret that far. Not he, oh, no. But he would drive
the city loan to par and then sell. And what a fat thing for himself among
others in so doing. Wisely enough he sensed that there was politics in all
this—shrewder and bigger men above and behind Stener. But what of that?
And how slyly and shrewdly they were sending Stener to him. It might be that
his name was becoming very potent in their political world here. And what might
that not mean!</p>
<p>“I tell you what I’d like to do, Mr. Stener,” he said, after
he had listened to his explanation and asked how much of the city loan he would
like to sell during the coming year. “I’ll be glad to undertake it.
But I’d like to have a day or two in which to think it over.”</p>
<p>“Why, certainly, certainly, Mr. Cowperwood,” replied Stener,
genially. “That’s all right. Take your time. If you know how it can
be done, just show me when you’re ready. By the way, what do you
charge?”</p>
<p>“Well, the stock exchange has a regular scale of charges which we brokers
are compelled to observe. It’s one-fourth of one per cent. on the par
value of bonds and loans. Of course, I may hav to add a lot of fictitious
selling—I’ll explain that to you later—but I won’t
charge you anything for that so long as it is a secret between us. I’ll
give you the best service I can, Mr. Stener. You can depend on that. Let me
have a day or two to think it over, though.”</p>
<p>He shook hands with Stener, and they parted. Cowperwood was satisfied that he
was on the verge of a significant combination, and Stener that he had found
someone on whom he could lean.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />