<p> ARTICLE II.Taxes upon Profit, or upon the Revenue arising from
Stock.</p>
<p>The revenue or profit arising from stock naturally divides itself into two
parts; that which pays the interest, and which belongs to the owner of the
stock; and that surplus part which is over and above what is necessary for
paying the interest.</p>
<p>This latter part of profit is evidently a subject not taxable directly. It
is the compensation, and, in most cases, it is no more than a very
moderate compensation for the risk and trouble of employing the stock. The
employer must have this compensation, otherwise he cannot, consistently
with his own interest, continue the employment. If he was taxed directly,
therefore, in proportion to the whole profit, he would be obliged either
to raise the rate of his profit, or to charge the tax upon the interest of
money; that is, to pay less interest. If he raised the rate of his profit
in proportion to the tax, the whole tax, though it might be advanced by
him, would be finally paid by one or other of two different sets of
people, according to the different ways in which he might employ the stock
of which he had the management. If he employed it as a farming stock, in
the cultivation of land, he could raise the rate of his profit only by
retaining a greater portion, or, what comes to the same thing, the price
of a greater portion, of the produce of the land; and as this could be
done only by a reduction of rent, the final payment of the tax would fall
upon the landlord. If he employed it as a mercantile or manufacturing
stock, he could raise the rate of his profit only by raising the price of
his goods; in which case, the final payment of the tax would fall
altogether upon the consumers of those goods. If he did not raise the rate
of his profit, he would be obliged to charge the whole tax upon that part
of it which was allotted for the interest of money. He could afford less
interest for whatever stock he borrowed, and the whole weight of the tax
would, in this case, fall ultimately upon the interest of money. So far as
he could not relieve himself from the tax in the one way, he would be
obliged to relieve himself in the other.</p>
<p>The interest of money seems, at first sight, a subject equally capable of
being taxed directly as the rent of land. Like the rent of land, it is a
neat produce, which remains, after completely compensating the whole risk
and trouble of employing the stock. As a tax upon the rent of land cannot
raise rents, because the neat produce which remains, after replacing the
stock of the farmer, together with his reasonable profit, cannot be
greater after the tax than before it, so, for the same reason, a tax upon
the interest of money could not raise the rate of interest; the quantity
of stock or money in the country, like the quantity of land, being
supposed to remain the same after the tax as before it. The ordinary rate
of profit, it has been shewn, in the first book, is everywhere regulated
by the quantity of stock to be employed, in proportion to the quantity of
the employment, or of the business which must be done by it. But the
quantity of the employment, or of the business to be done by stock, could
neither be increased nor diminished by any tax upon the interest of money.
If the quantity of the stock to be employed, therefore, was neither
increased nor diminished by it, the ordinary rate of profit would
necessarily remain the same. But the portion of this profit, necessary for
compensating the risk and trouble of the employer, would likewise remain
the same; that risk and trouble being in no respect altered. The residue,
therefore, that portion which belongs to the owner of the stock, and which
pays the interest of money, would necessarily remain the same too. At
first sight, therefore, the interest of money seems to be a subject as fit
to be taxed directly as the rent of land.</p>
<p>There are, however, two different circumstances, which render the interest
of money a much less proper subject of direct taxation than the rent of
land.</p>
<p>First, the quantity and value of the land which any man possesses, can
never be a secret, and can always be ascertained with great exactness. But
the whole amount of the capital stock which he possesses is almost always
a secret, and can scarce ever be ascertained with tolerable exactness. It
is liable, besides, to almost continual variations. A year seldom passes
away, frequently not a month, sometimes scarce a single day, in which it
does not rise or fall more or less. An inquisition into every man's
private circumstances, and an inquisition which, in order to accommodate
the tax to them, watched over all the fluctuations of his fortune, would
be a source of such continual and endless vexation as no person could
support.</p>
<p>Secondly, land is a subject which cannot be removed; whereas stock easily
may. The proprietor of land is necessarily a citizen of the particular
country in which his estate lies. The proprietor of stock is properly a
citizen of the world, and is not necessarily attached to any particular
country. He would be apt to abandon the country in which he was exposed to
a vexatious inquisition, in order to be assessed to a burdensome tax; and
would remove his stock to some other country, where he could either carry
on his business, or enjoy his fortune more at his ease. By removing his
stock, he would put an end to all the industry which it had maintained in
the country which he left. Stock cultivates land; stock employs labour. A
tax which tended to drive away stock from any particular country, would so
far tend to dry up every source of revenue, both to the sovereign and to
the society. Not only the profits of stock, but the rent of land, and the
wages of labour, would necessarily be more or less diminished by its
removal.</p>
<p>The nations, accordingly, who have attempted to tax the revenue arising
from stock, instead of any severe inquisition of this kind, have been
obliged to content themselves with some very loose, and, therefore, more
or less arbitrary estimation. The extreme inequality and uncertainty of a
tax assessed in this manner, can be compensated only by its extreme
moderation; in consequence of which, every man finds himself rated so very
much below his real revenue, that he gives himself little disturbance
though his neighbour should be rated somewhat lower.</p>
<p>By what is called the land tax in England, it was intended that the stock
should be taxed in the same proportion as land. When the tax upon land was
at four shillings in the pound, or at one-fifth of the supposed rent, it
was intended that stock should be taxed at one-fifth of the supposed
interest. When the present annual land tax was first imposed, the legal
rate of interest was six per cent. Every hundred pounds stock,
accordingly, was supposed to be taxed at twenty-four shillings, the fifth
part of six pounds. Since the legal rate of interest has been reduced to
five per cent. every hundred pounds stock is supposed to be taxed at
twenty shillings only. The sum to be raised, by what is called the land
tax, was divided between the country and the principal towns. The greater
part of it was laid upon the country; and of what was laid upon the towns,
the greater part was assessed upon the houses. What remained to be
assessed upon the stock or trade of the towns (for the stock upon the land
was not meant to be taxed) was very much below the real value of that
stock or trade. Whatever inequalities, therefore, there might be in the
original assessment, gave little disturbance. Every parish and district
still continues to be rated for its land, its houses, and its stock,
according to the original assessment; and the almost universal prosperity
of the country, which, in most places, has raised very much the value of
all these, has rendered those inequalities of still less importance now.
The rate, too, upon each district, continuing always the same, the
uncertainty of this tax, so far as it might he assessed upon the stock of
any individual, has been very much diminished, as well as rendered of much
less consequence. If the greater part of the lands of England are not
rated to the land tax at half their actual value, the greater part of the
stock of England is, perhaps, scarce rated at the fiftieth part of its
actual value. In some towns, the whole land tax is assessed upon houses;
as in Westminster, where stock and trade are free. It is otherwise in
London.</p>
<p>In all countries, a severe inquisition into the circumstances of private
persons has been carefully avoided.</p>
<p>At Hamburg, {Memoires concernant les Droits, tom. i, p.74} every
inhabitant is obliged to pay to the state one fourth per cent. of all that
he possesses; and as the wealth of the people of Hamburg consists
principally in stock, this tax maybe considered as a tax upon stock. Every
man assesses himself, and, in the presence of the magistrate, puts
annually into the public coffer a certain sum of money, which he declares
upon oath, to be one fourth per cent. of all that he possesses, but
without declaring what it amounts to, or being liable to any examination
upon that subject. This tax is generally supposed to be paid with great
fidelity. In a small republic, where the people have entire confidence in
their magistrates, are convinced of the necessity of the tax for the
support of the state, and believe that it will be faithfully applied to
that purpose, such conscientious and voluntary payment may sometimes be
expected. It is not peculiar to the people of Hamburg.</p>
<p>The canton of Underwald, in Switzerland, is frequently ravaged by storms
and inundations, and it is thereby exposed to extraordinary expenses. Upon
such occasions the people assemble, and every one is said to declare with
the greatest frankness what he is worth, in order to be taxed accordingly.
At Zurich, the law orders, that in cases of necessity, every one should be
taxed in proportion to his revenue; the amount of which he is obliged to
declare upon oath. They have no suspicion, it is said, that any of their
fellow citizens will deceive them. At Basil, the principal revenue of the
state arises from a small custom upon goods exported. All the citizens
make oath, that they will pay every three months all the taxes imposed by
law. All merchants, and even all inn-keepers, are trusted with keeping
themselves the account of the goods which they sell, either within or
without the territory. At the end of every three months, they send this
account to the treasurer, with the amount of the tax computed at the
bottom of it. It is not suspected that the revenue suffers by this
confidence. {Memoires concernant les Droits, tom. i p. 163, 167,171.}</p>
<p>To oblige every citizen to declare publicly upon oath, the amount of his
fortune, must not, it seems, in those Swiss cantons, be reckoned a
hardship. At Hamburg it would be reckoned the greatest. Merchants engaged
in the hazardous projects of trade, all tremble at the thoughts of being
obliged, at all times, to expose the real state of their circumstances.
The ruin of their credit, and the miscarriage of their projects, they
foresee, would too often be the consequence. A sober and parsimonious
people, who are strangers to all such projects, do not feel that they have
occasion for any such concealment.</p>
<p>In Holland, soon after the exaltation of the late prince of Orange to the
stadtholdership, a tax of two per cent. or the fiftieth penny, as it was
called, was imposed upon the whole substance of every citizen. Every
citizen assesed himself, and paid his tax, in the same manner as at
Hamburg, and it was in general supposed to have been paid with great
fidelity. The people had at that time the greatest affection for their new
government, which they had just established by a general insurrection. The
tax was to be paid but once, in order to relieve the state in a particular
exigency. It was, indeed, too heavy to be permanent. In a country where
the market rate of interest seldom exceeds three per cent., a tax of two
per cent. amounts to thirteen shillings and four pence in the pound, upon
the highest neat revenue which is commonly drawn from stock. It is a tax
which very few people could pay, without encroaching more or less upon
their capitals. In a particular exigency, the people may, from great
public zeal, make a great effort, and give up even a part of their
capital, in order to relieve the state. But it is impossible that they
should continue to do so for any considerable time; and if they did, the
tax would soon ruin them so completely, as to render them altogether
incapable of supporting the state.</p>
<p>The tax upon stock, imposed by the land tax bill in England, though it is
proportioned to the capital, is not intended to diminish or, take away any
part of that capital. It is meant only to be a tax upon the interest of
money, proportioned to that upon the rent of land; so that when the latter
is at four shillings in the pound, the former may be at four shillings in
the pound too. The tax at Hamburg, and the still more moderate taxes of
Underwald and Zurich, are meant, in the same manner, to be taxes, not upon
the capital, but upon the interest or neat revenue of stock. That of
Holland was meant to be a tax upon the capital.</p>
<p>Taxes upon the Profit of particular Employments.</p>
<p>In some countries, extraordinary taxes are imposed upon the profits of
stock; sometimes when employed in particular branches of trade, and
sometimes when employed in agriculture.</p>
<p>Of the former kind, are in England, the tax upon hawkers and pedlars, that
upon hackney-coaches and chairs, and that which the keepers of ale-houses
pay for a licence to retail ale and spiritous liquors. During the late
war, another tax of the same kind was proposed upon shops. The war having
been undertaken, it was said, in defence of the trade of the country, the
merchants, who were to profit by it, ought to contribute towards the
support of it.</p>
<p>A tax, however, upon the profits of stock employed in any particular
branch of trade, can never fall finally upon the dealers (who must in all
ordinary cases have their reasonable profit, and, where the competition is
free, can seldom have more than that profit), but always upon the
consumers, who must be obliged to pay in the price of the goods the tax
which the dealer advances; and generally with some overcharge.</p>
<p>A tax of this kind, when it is proportioned to the trade of the dealer, is
finally paid by the consumer, and occasions no oppression to the dealer.
When it is not so proportioned, but is the same upon all dealers, though
in this case, too, it is finally paid by the consumer, yet it favours the
great, and occasions some oppression to the small dealer. The tax of five
shillings a-week upon every hackney coach, and that of ten shillings
a-year upon every hackney chair, so far as it is advanced by the different
keepers of such coaches and chairs, is exactly enough proportioned to the
extent of their respective dealings. It neither favours the great, nor
oppresses the smaller dealer. The tax of twenty shillings a-year for a
licence to sell ale; of forty shillings for a licence to sell spiritous
liquors; and of forty shillings more for a licence to sell wine, being the
same upon all retailers, must necessarily give some advantage to the
great, and occasion some oppression to the small dealers. The former must
find it more easy to get back the tax in the price of their goods than the
latter. The moderation of the tax, however, renders this inequality of
less importance; and it may to many people appear not improper to give
some discouragement to the multiplication of little ale-houses. The tax
upon shops, it was intended, should be the same upon all shops. It could
not well have been otherwise. It would have been impossible to proportion,
with tolerable exactness, the tax upon a shop to the extent of the trade
carried on in it, without such an inquisition as would have been
altogether insupportable in a free country. If the tax had been
considerable, it would have oppressed the small, and forced almost the
whole retail trade into the hands of the great dealers. The competition of
the former being taken away, the latter would have enjoyed a monopoly of
the trade; and, like all other monopolists, would soon have combined to
raise their profits much beyond what was necessary for the payment of the
tax. The final payment, instead of falling upon the shop-keeper, would
have fallen upon the consumer, with a considerable overcharge to the
profit of the shop-keeper. For these reasons, the project of a tax upon
shops was laid aside, and in the room of it was substituted the subsidy,
1759.</p>
<p>What in France is called the personal taille, is perhaps, the most
important tax upon the profits of stock employed in agriculture, that is
levied in any part of Europe.</p>
<p>In the disorderly state of Europe, during the prevalence of the feudal
government, the sovereign was obliged to content himself with taxing those
who were too weak to refuse to pay taxes. The great lords, though willing
to assist him upon particular emergencies, refused to subject themselves
to any constant tax, and he was not strong enough to force them. The
occupiers of land all over Europe were, the greater part of them,
originally bond-men. Through the greater part of Europe, they were
gradually emancipated. Some of them acquired the property of landed
estates, which they held by some base or ignoble tenure, sometimes under
the king, and sometimes under some other great lord, like the ancient
copy-holders of England. Others, without acquiring the property, obtained
leases for terms of years, of the lands which they occupied under their
lord, and thus became less dependent upon him. The great lords seem to
have beheld the degree of prosperity and independency, which this inferior
order of men had thus come to enjoy, with a malignant and contemptuous
indignation, and willingly consented that the sovereign should tax them.
In some countries, this tax was confined to the lands which were held in
property by an ignoble tenure; and, in this case, the taille was said to
be real. The land tax established by the late king of Sardinia, and the
taille in the provinces of Languedoc, Provence, Dauphine, and Britanny; in
the generality of Montauban, and in the elections of Agen and Condom, as
well as in some other districts of France; are taxes upon lands held in
property by an ignoble tenure. In other countries, the tax was laid upon
the supposed profits of all those who held, in farm or lease, lands
belonging to other people, whatever might be the tenure by which the
proprietor held them; and in this case, the taille was said to be
personal. In the greater part of those provinces of France, which are
called the countries of elections, the taille is of this kind. The real
taille, as it is imposed only upon a part of the lands of the country, is
necessarily an unequal, but it is not always an arbitrary tax, though it
is so upon some occasions. The personal taille, as it is intended to be
proportioned to the profits of a certain class of people, which can only
be guessed at, is necessarily both arbitrary and unequal.</p>
<p>In France, the personal taille at present (1775) annually imposed upon the
twenty generalities, called the countries of elections, amounts to
40,107,239 livres, 16 sous. {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc tom. ii,
p.17.} the proportion in which this sum is assessed upon those different
provinces, varies from year to year, according to the reports which are
made to the king's council concerning the goodness or badness of the
crops, as well as other circumstances, which may either increase or
diminish their respective abilities to pay. Each generality is divided
into a certain number of elections; and the proportion in which the sum
imposed upon the whole generality is divided among those different
elections, varies likewise from year to year, according to the reports
made to the council concerning their respective abilities. It seems
impossible, that the council, with the best intentions, can ever
proportion, with tolerable exactness, either of these two assessments to
the real abilities of the province or district upon which they are
respectively laid. Ignorance and misinformation must always, more or less,
mislead the most upright council. The proportion which each parish ought
to support of what is assessed upon the whole election, and that which
each individual ought to support of what is assessed upon his particular
parish, are both in the same manner varied from year to year, according as
circumstances are supposed to require. These circumstances are judged of,
in the one case, by the officers of the election, in the other, by those
of the parish; and both the one and the other are, more or less, under the
direction and influence of the intendant. Not only ignorance and
misinformation, but friendship, party animosity, and private resentment,
are said frequently to mislead such assessors. No man subject to such a
tax, it is evident, can ever be certain, before he is assessed, of what he
is to pay. He cannot even be certain after he is assessed. If any person
has been taxed who ought to have been exempted, or if any person has been
taxed beyond his proportion, though both must pay in the mean time, yet if
they complain, and make good their complaints, the whole parish is
reimposed next year, in order to reimburse them. If any of the
contributors become bankrupt or insolvent, the collector is obliged to
advance his tax; and the whole parish is reimposed next year, in order to
reimburse the collector. If the collector himself should become bankrupt,
the parish which elects him must answer for his conduct to the
receiver-general of the election. But, as it might be troublesome for the
receiver to prosecute the whole parish, he takes at his choice five or six
of the richest contributors, and obliges them to make good what had been
lost by the insolvency of the collector. The parish is afterwards
reimposed, in order to reimburse those five or six. Such reimpositions are
always over and above the taille of the particular year in which they are
laid on.</p>
<p>When a tax is imposed upon the profits of stock in a particular branch of
trade, the traders are all careful to bring no more goods to market than
what they can sell at a price sufficient to reimburse them from advancing
the tax. Some of them withdraw a part of their stocks from the trade, and
the market is more sparingly supplied than before. The price of the goods
rises, and the final payment of the tax falls upon the consumer. But when
a tax is imposed upon the profits of stock employed in agriculture, it is
not the interest of the farmers to withdraw any part of their stock from
that employment. Each farmer occupies a certain quantity of land, for
which he pays rent. For the proper cultivation of this land, a certain
quantity of stock is necessary; and by withdrawing any part of this
necessary quantity, the farmer is not likely to be more able to pay either
the rent or the tax. In order to pay the tax, it can never be his interest
to diminish the quantity of his produce, nor consequently to supply the
market more sparingly than before. The tax, therefore, will never enable
him to raise the price of his produce, so as to reimburse himself, by
throwing the final payment upon the consumer. The farmer, however, must
have his reasonable profit as well as every other dealer, otherwise he
must give up the trade. After the imposition of a tax of this kind, he can
get this reasonable profit only by paying less rent to the landlord. The
more he is obliged to pay in the way of tax, the less he can afford to pay
in the way of rent. A tax of this kind, imposed during the currency of a
lease, may, no doubt, distress or ruin the farmer. Upon the renewal of the
lease, it must always fall upon the landlord.</p>
<p>In the countries where the personal taille takes place, the farmer is
commonly assessed in proportion to the stock which he appears to employ in
cultivation. He is, upon this account, frequently afraid to have a good
team of horses or oxen, but endeavours to cultivate with the meanest and
most wretched instruments of husbandry that he can. Such is his distrust
in the justice of his assessors, that he counterfeits poverty, and wishes
to appear scarce able to pay anything, for fear of being obliged to pay
too much. By this miserable policy, he does not, perhaps, always consult
his own interest in the most effectual manner; and he probably loses more
by the diminution of his produce, than he saves by that of his tax.
Though, in consequence of this wretched cultivation, the market is, no
doubt, somewhat worse supplied; yet the small rise of price which this may
occasion, as it is not likely even to indemnify the farmer for the
diminution of his produce, it is still less likely to enable him to pay
more rent to the landlord. The public, the farmer, the landlord, all
suffer more or less by this degraded cultivation. That the personal taille
tends, in many different ways, to discourage cultivation, and consequently
to dry up the principal source of the wealth of every great country, I
have already had occasion to observe in the third book of this Inquiry.</p>
<p>What are called poll-taxes in the southern provinces of North America, and
the West India islands, annual taxes of so much a-head upon every negro,
are properly taxes upon the profits of a certain species of stock employed
in agriculture. As the planters, are the greater part of them, both
farmers and landlords, the final payment of the tax falls upon them in
their quality of landlords, without any retribution.</p>
<p>Taxes of so much a head upon the bondmen employed in cultivation, seem
anciently to have been common all over Europe. There subsists at present a
tax of this kind in the empire of Russia. It is probably upon this account
that poll-taxes of all kinds have often been represented as badges of
slavery. Every tax, however, is, to the person who pays it, a badge, not
of slavery, but of liberty. It denotes that he is subject to government,
indeed; but that, as he has some property, he cannot himself be the
property of a master. A poll tax upon slaves is altogether different from
a poll-tax upon freemen. The latter is paid by the persons upon whom it is
imposed; the former, by a different set of persons. The latter is either
altogether arbitrary, or altogether unequal, and, in most cases, is both
the one and the other; the former, though in some respects unequal,
different slaves being of different values, is in no respect arbitrary.
Every master, who knows the number of his own slaves, knows exactly what
he has to pay. Those different taxes, however, being called by the same
name, have been considered as of the same nature.</p>
<p>The taxes which in Holland are imposed upon men and maid servants, are
taxes, not upon stock, but upon expense; and so far resemble the taxes
upon consumable commodities. The tax of a guinea a-head for every
man-servant, which has lately been imposed in Great Britain, is of the
same kind. It falls heaviest upon the middling rank. A man of two hundred
a-year may keep a single man-servant. A man of ten thousand a-year will
not keep fifty. It does not affect the poor.</p>
<p>Taxes upon the profits of stock, in particular employments, can never
affect the interest of money. Nobody will lend his money for less interest
to those who exercise the taxed, than to those who exercise the untaxed
employments. Taxes upon the revenue arising from stock in all employments,
where the government attempts to levy them with any degree of exactness,
will, in many cases, fall upon the interest of money. The vingtieme, or
twentieth penny, in France, is a tax of the same kind with what is called
the land tax in England, and is assessed, in the same manner, upon the
revenue arising upon land, houses, and stock. So far as it affects stock,
it is assessed, though not with great rigour, yet with much more exactness
than that part of the land tax in England which is imposed upon the same
fund. It, in many cases, falls altogether upon the interest of money.
Money is frequently sunk in France, upon what are called contracts for the
constitution of a rent; that is, perpetual annuities, redeemable at any
time by the debtor, upon payment of the sum originally advanced, but of
which this redemption is not exigible by the creditor except in particular
cases. The vingtieme seems not to have raised the rate of those annuities,
though it is exactly levied upon them all.</p>
<h2> APPENDIX TO ARTICLES I. AND II.—Taxes upon the Capital Value of Lands, Houses, and Stock. </h2>
<p>While property remains in the possession of the same person, whatever
permanent taxes may have been imposed upon it, they have never been
intended to diminish or take away any part of its capital value, but only
some part of the revenue arising from it. But when property changes hands,
when it is transmitted either from the dead to the living, or from the
living to the living, such taxes have frequently been imposed upon it as
necessarily take away some part of its capital value.</p>
<p>The transference of all sorts of property from the dead to the living, and
that of immoveable property of land and houses from the living to the
living, are transactions which are in their nature either public and
notorious, or such as cannot be long concealed. Such transactions,
therefore, may be taxed directly. The transference of stock or moveable
property, from the living to the living, by the lending of money, is
frequently a secret transaction, and may always be made so. It cannot
easily, therefore, be taxed directly. It has been taxed indirectly in two
different ways; first, by requiring that the deed, containing the
obligation to repay, should be written upon paper or parchment which had
paid a certain stamp duty, otherwise not to be valid; secondly, by
requiring, under the like penalty of invalidity, that it should be
recorded either in a public or secret register, and by imposing certain
duties upon such registration. Stamp duties, and duties of registration,
have frequently been imposed likewise upon the deeds transferring property
of all kinds from the dead to the living, and upon those transferring
immoveable property from the living to the living; transactions which
might easily have been taxed directly.</p>
<p>The vicesima hereditatum, or the twentieth penny of inheritances, imposed
by Augustus upon the ancient Romans, was a tax upon the transference of
property from the dead to the living. Dion Cassius, { Lib. 55. See also
Burman. de Vectigalibus Pop. Rom. cap. xi. and Bouchaud de l'impot du
vingtieme sur les successions.} the author who writes concerning it the
least indistinctly, says, that it was imposed upon all successions,
legacies and donations, in case of death, except upon those to the nearest
relations, and to the poor.</p>
<p>Of the same kind is the Dutch tax upon successions. {See Memoires
concernant les Droits, etc. tom i, p. 225.} Collateral successions are
taxed according to the degree of relation, from five to thirty per cent.
upon the whole value of the succession. Testamentary donations, or
legacies to collaterals, are subject to the like duties. Those from
husband to wife, or from wife to husband, to the fiftieth penny. The
luctuosa hereditas, the mournful succession of ascendants to descendants,
to the twentieth penny only. Direct successions, or those of descendants
to ascendants, pay no tax. The death of a father, to such of his children
as live in the same house with him, is seldom attended with any increase,
and frequently with a considerable diminution of revenue; by the loss of
his industry, of his office, or of some life-rent estate, of which he may
have been in possession. That tax would be cruel and oppressive, which
aggravated their loss, by taking from them any part of his succession. It
may, however, sometimes be otherwise with those children, who, in the
language of the Roman law, are said to be emancipated; in that of the
Scotch law, to be foris-familiated; that is, who have received their
portion, have got families of their own, and are supported by funds
separate and independent of those of their father. Whatever part of his
succession might come to such children, would be a real addition to their
fortune, and might, therefore, perhaps, without more inconveniency than
what attends all duties of this kind, be liable to some tax. The
casualties of the feudal law were taxes upon the transference of land,
both from the dead to the living, and from the living to the living. In
ancient times, they constituted, in every part of Europe, one of the
principal branches of the revenue of the crown.</p>
<p>The heir of every immediate vassal of the crown paid a certain duty,
generally a year's rent, upon receiving the investiture of the estate. If
the heir was a minor, the whole rents of the estate, during the
continuance of the minority, devolved to the superior, without any other
charge besides the maintenance of the minor, and the payment of the
widow's dower, when there happened to be a dowager upon the land. When the
minor came to de of age, another tax, called relief, was still due to the
superior, which generally amounted likewise to a year's rent. A long
minority, which, in the present times, so frequently disburdens a great
estate of all its incumbrances, and restores the family to their ancient
splendour, could in those times have no such effect. The waste, and not
the disincumbrance of the estate, was the common effect of a long
minority.</p>
<p>By a feudal law, the vassal could not alienate without the consent of his
superior, who generally extorted a fine or composition on granting it.
This fine, which was at first arbitrary, came, in many countries, to be
regulated at a certain portion of the price of the land. In some
countries, where the greater part of the other feudal customs have gone
into disuse, this tax upon the alienation of land still continues to make
a very considerable branch of the revenue of the sovereign. In the canton
of Berne it is so high as a sixth part of the price of all noble fiefs,
and a tenth part of that of all ignoble ones. {Memoires concernant les
Droits, etc, tom.i p.154} In the canton of Lucern, the tax upon the sale
of land is not universal, and takes place only in certain districts. But
if any person sells his land in order to remove out of the territory, he
pays ten per cent. upon the whole price of the sale. {id. p.157.} Taxes of
the same kind, upon the sale either of all lands, or of lands held by
certain tenures, take place in many other countries, and make a more or
less considerable branch of the revenue of the sovereign.</p>
<p>Such transactions may be taxed indirectly, by means either of stamp
duties, or of duties upon registration; and those duties either may, or
may not, be proportioned to the value of the subject which is transferred.</p>
<p>In Great Britain, the stamp duties are higher or lower, not so much
according to the value of the property transferred (an eighteen-penny or
half-crown stamp being sufficient upon a bond for the largest sum of
money), as according to the nature of the deed. The highest do not exceed
six pounds upon every sheet of paper, or skin of parchment; and these high
duties fall chiefly upon grants from the crown, and upon certain law
proceedings, without any regard to the value of the subject. There are, in
Great Britain, no duties on the registration of deeds or writings, except
the fees of the officers who keep the register; and these are seldom more
than a reasonable recompence for their labour. The crown derives no
revenue from them.</p>
<p>In Holland {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. i. p 223, 224, 225.}
there are both stamp duties and duties upon registration; which in some
cases are, and in some are not, proportioned to the value of the property
transferred. All testaments must be written upon stamped paper, of which
the price is proportioned to the property disposed of; so that there are
stamps which cost from three pence or three stivers a-sheet, to three
hundred florins, equal to about twenty-seven pounds ten shillings of our
money. If the stamp is of an inferior price to what the testator ought to
have made use of, his succession is confiscated. This is over and above
all their other taxes on succession. Except bills of exchange, and some
other mercantile bills, all other deeds, bonds, and contracts, are subject
to a stamp duty. This duty, however, does not rise in proportion to the
value of the subject. All sales of land and of houses, and all mortgages
upon either, must be registered, and, upon registration, pay a duty to the
state of two and a-half per cent. upon the amount of the price or of the
mortgage. This duty is extended to the sale of all ships and vessels of
more than two tons burden, whether decked or undecked. These, it seems,
are considered as a sort of houses upon the water. The sale of moveables,
when it is ordered by a court of justice, is subject to the like duty of
two and a-half per cent.</p>
<p>In France, there are both stamp duties and duties upon registration. The
former are considered as a branch of the aids of excise, and, in the
provinces where those duties take place, are levied by the excise
officers. The latter are considered as a branch of the domain of the crown
and are levied by a different set of officers.</p>
<p>Those modes of taxation by stamp duties and by duties upon registration,
are of very modern invention. In the course of little more than a century,
however, stamp duties have, in Europe, become almost universal, and duties
upon registration extremely common. There is no art which one government
sooner learns of another, than that of draining money from the pockets of
the people.</p>
<p>Taxes upon the transference of property from the dead to the living, fall
finally, as well as immediately, upon the persons to whom the property is
transferred. Taxes upon the sale of land fall altogether upon the seller.
The seller is almost always under the necessity of selling, and must,
therefore, take such a price as he can get. The buyer is scarce ever under
the necessity of buying, and will, therefore, only give such a price as he
likes. He considers what the land will cost him, in tax and price
together. The more he is obliged to pay in the way of tax, the less he
will be disposed to give in the way of price. Such taxes, therefore, fall
almost always upon a necessitous person, and must, therefore, be
frequently very cruel and oppressive. Taxes upon the sale of new-built
houses, where the building is sold without the ground, fall generally upon
the buyer, because the builder must generally have his profit; otherwise
he must give up the trade. If he advances the tax, therefore, the buyer
must generally repay it to him. Taxes upon the sale of old houses, for the
same reason as those upon the sale of land, fall generally upon the
seller; whom, in most cases, either conveniency or necessity obliges to
sell. The number of new-built houses that are annually brought to market,
is more or less regulated by the demand. Unless the demand is such as to
afford the builder his profit, after paying all expenses, he will build no
more houses. The number of old houses which happen at any time to come to
market, is regulated by accidents, of which the greater part have no
relation to the demand. Two or three great bankruptcies in a mercantile
town, will bring many houses to sale, which must be sold for what can be
got for them. Taxes upon the sale of ground-rents fall altogether upon the
seller, for the same reason as those upon the sale of lands. Stamp duties,
and duties upon the registration of bonds and contracts for borrowed
money, fall altogether upon the borrower, and, in fact, are always paid by
him. Duties of the same kind upon law proceedings fall upon the suitors.
They reduce to both the capital value of the subject in dispute. The more
it costs to acquire any property, the less must be the neat value of it
when acquired.</p>
<p>All taxes upon the transference of property of every kind, so far as they
diminish the capital value of that property, tend to diminish the funds
destined for the maintenance of productive labour. They are all more or
less unthrifty taxes that increase the revenue of the sovereign, which
seldom maintains any but unproductive labourers, at the expense of the
capital of the people, which maintains none but productive.</p>
<p>Such taxes, even when they are proportioned to the value of the property
transferred, are still unequal; the frequency of transference not being
always equal in property of equal value. When they are not proportioned to
this value, which is the case with the greater part of the stamp duties
and duties of registration, they are still more so. They are in no respect
arbitrary, but are, or may be, in all cases, perfectly clear and certain.
Though they sometimes fall upon the person who is not very able to pay,
the time of payment is, in most cases, sufficiently convenient for him.
When the payment becomes due, he must, in most cases, have the more to
pay. They are levied at very little expense, and in general subject the
contributors to no other inconveniency, besides always the unavoidable one
of paying the tax. In France, the stamp duties are not much complained of.
Those of registration, which they call the Controle, are. They give
occasion, it is pretended, to much extortion in the officers of the
farmers-general who collect the tax, which is in a great measure arbitrary
and uncertain. In the greater part of the libels which have been written
against the present system of finances in France, the abuses of the
controle make a principal article. Uncertainty, however, does not seem to
be necessarily inherent in the nature of such taxes. If the popular
complaints are well founded, the abuse must arise, not so much from the
nature of the tax as from the want of precision and distinctness in the
words of the edicts or laws which impose it.</p>
<p>The registration of mortgages, and in general of all rights upon
immoveable property, as it gives great security both to creditors and
purchasers, is extremely advantageous to the public. That of the greater
part of deeds of other kinds, is frequently inconvenient and even
dangerous to individuals, without any advantage to the public. All
registers which, it is acknowledged, ought to be kept secret, ought
certainly never to exist. The credit of individuals ought certainly never
to depend upon so very slender a security, as the probity and religion of
the inferior officers of revenue. But where the fees of registration have
been made a source of revenue to the sovereign, register-offices have
commonly been multiplied without end, both for the deeds which ought to be
registered, and for those which ought not. In France there are several
different sorts of secret registers. This abuse, though not perhaps a
necessary, it must be acknowledged, is a very natural effect of such
taxes.</p>
<p>Such stamp duties as those in England upon cards and dice, upon newspapers
and periodical pamphlets, etc. are properly taxes upon consumption; the
final payment falls upon the persons who use or consume such commodities.
Such stamp duties as those upon licences to retail ale, wine, and
spiritous liquors, though intended, perhaps, to fall upon the profits of
the retailers, are likewise finally paid by the consumers of those
liquors. Such taxes, though called by the same name, and levied by the
same officers, and in the same manner with the stamp duties above
mentioned upon the transference of property, are, however, of a quite
different nature, and fall upon quite different funds.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />