<p>Taxes which are proportioned, not in the Rent, but to the Produce of Land.</p>
<p>Taxes upon the produce of land are, In reality, taxes upon the rent; and
though they may be originally advanced by the farmer, are finally paid by
the landlord. When a certain portion of the produce is to be paid away for
a tax, the farmer computes as well as he can, what the value of this
portion is, one year with another, likely to amount to, and he makes a
proportionable abatement in the rent which he agrees to pay to the
landlord. There is no farmer who does not compute beforehand what the
church tythe, which is a land tax of this kind, is, one year with another,
likely to amount to.</p>
<p>The tythe, and every other land tax of this kind, under the appearance of
perfect equality, are very unequal taxes; a certain portion of the produce
being in differrent situations, equivalent to a very different portion of
the rent. In some very rich lands, the produce is so great, that the one
half of it is fully sufficient to replace to the farmer his capital
employed in cultivation, together with the ordinary profits of farming
stock in the neighbourhood. The other half, or, what comes to the same
thing, the value of the other half, he could afford to pay as rent to the
landlord, if there was no tythe. But if a tenth of the produce is taken
from him in the way of tythe, he must require an abatement of the fifth
part of his rent, otherwise he cannot get back his capital with the
ordinary profit. In this case, the rent of the landlord, instead of
amounting to a half, or five-tenths of the whole produce, will amount only
to four-tenths of it. In poorer lands, on the contrary, the produce is
sometimes so small, and the expense of cultivation so great, that it
requires four-fifths of the whole produce, to replace to the farmer his
capital with the ordinary profit. In this case, though there was no tythe,
the rent of the landlord could amount to no more than one-fifth or
two-tenths of the whole produce. But if the farmer pays one-tenth of the
produce in the way of tythe, he must require an equal abatement of the
rent of the landlord, which will thus be reduced to one-tenth only of the
whole produce. Upon the rent of rich lands the tythe may sometimes be a
tax of no more than one-fifth part, or four shillings in the pound;
whereas upon that of poorer lands, it may sometimes be a tax of one half,
or of ten shillings in the pound.</p>
<p>The tythe, as it is frequently a very unequal tax upon the rent, so it is
always a great discouragement, both to the improvements of the landlord,
and to the cultivation of the farmer. The one cannot venture to make the
most important, which are generally the most expensive improvements; nor
the other to raise the most valuable, which are generally, too, the most
expensive crops; when the church, which lays out no part of the expense,
is to share so very largely in the profit. The cultivation of madder was,
for a long time, confined by the tythe to the United Provinces, which,
being presbyterian countries, and upon that account exempted from this
destructive tax, enjoyed a sort of monopoly of that useful dyeing drug
against the rest of Europe. The late attempts to introduce the culture of
this plant into England, have been made only in consequence of the
statute, which enacted that five shillings an acre should be received in
lieu of all manner of tythe upon madder.</p>
<p>As through the greater part of Europe, the church, so in many different
countries of Asia, the state, is principally supported by a land tax,
proportioned not to the rent, but to the produce of the land. In China,
the principal revenue of the sovereign consists in a tenth part of the
produce of all the lands of the empire. This tenth part, however, is
estimated so very moderately, that, in many provinces, it is said not to
exceed a thirtieth part of the ordinary produce. The land tax or land rent
which used to be paid to the Mahometan government of Bengal, before that
country fell into the hands of the English East India company, is said to
have amounted to about a fifth part of the produce. The land tax of
ancient Egypt is said likewise to have amounted to a fifth part.</p>
<p>In Asia, this sort of land tax is said to interest the sovereign in the
improvement and cultivation of land. The sovereigns of China, those of
Bengal while under the Mahometan govermnent, and those of ancient Egypt,
are said, accordingly, to have been extremely attentive to the making and
maintaining of good roads and navigable canals, in order to increase, as
much as possible, both the quantity and value of every part of the produce
of the land, by procuring to every part of it the most extensive market
which their own dominions could afford. The tythe of the church is divided
into such small portions that no one of its proprietors can have any
interest of this kind. The parson of a parish could never find his
account, in making a road or canal to a distant part of the country, in
order to extend the market for the produce of his own particular parish.
Such taxes, when destined for the maintenance of the state, have some
advantages, which may serve in some measure to balance their
inconveniency. When destined for the maintenance of the church, they are
attended with nothing but inconveniency.</p>
<p>Taxes upon the produce of land may be levied, either in kind, or,
according to a certain valuation in money.</p>
<p>The parson of a parish, or a gentleman of small fortune who lives upon his
estate, may sometimes, perhaps find some advantage in receiving, the one
his tythe, and the other his rent, in kind. The quantity to be collected,
and the district within which it is to be collected, are so small, that
they both can oversee, with their own eyes, the collection and disposal of
every part of what is due to them. A gentleman of great fortune, who lived
in the capital, would be in danger of suffering much by the neglect, and
more by the fraud, of his factors and agents, if the rents of an estate in
a distant province were to be paid to him in this manner. The loss of the
sovereign, from the abuse and depredation of his tax-gatherers, would
necessarily be much greater. The servants of the most careless private
person are, perhaps, more under the eye of their master than those of the
most careful prince; and a public revenue, which was paid in kind, would
suffer so much from the mismanagement of the collectors, that a very small
part of what was levied upon the people would ever arrive at the treasury
of the prince. Some part of the public revenue of China, however, is said
to be paid in this manner. The mandarins and other tax-gatherers will, no
doubt, find their advantage in continuing the practice of a payment, which
is so much more liable to abuse than any payment in money.</p>
<p>A tax upon the produce of land, which is levied in money, may be levied,
either according to a valuation, which varies with all the variations of
the market price; or according to a fixed valuation, a bushel of wheat,
for example, being always valued at one and the same money price, whatever
may be the state of the market. The produce of a tax levied in the former
way will vary only according to the variations in the real produce of the
land, according to the improvement or neglect of cultivation. The produce
of a tax levied in the latter way will vary, not only according to the
variations in the produce of the land, but according both to those in the
value of the precious metals, and those in the quantity of those metals
which is at different times contained in coin of the same denomination.
The produce of the former will always bear the same proportion to the
value of the real produce of the land. The produce of the latter may, at
different times, bear very different proportions to that value.</p>
<p>When, instead either of a certain portion of the produce of land, or of
the price of a certain portion, a certain sum of money is to be paid in
full compensation for all tax or tythe; the tax becomes, in this case,
exactly of the same nature with the land tax of England. It neither rises
nor falls with the rent of the land. It neither encourages nor discourages
improvement. The tythe in the greater part of those parishes which pay
what is called a modus, in lieu of all other tythe is a tax of this kind.
During the Mahometan government of Bengal, instead of the payment in kind
of the fifth part of the produce, a modus, and, it is said, a very
moderate one, was established in the greater part of the districts or
zemindaries of the country. Some of the servants of the East India
company, under pretence of restoring the public revenue to its proper
value, have, in some provinces, exchanged this modus for a payment in
kind. Under their management, this change is likely both to discourage
cultivation, and to give new opportunities for abuse in the collection of
the public revenue, which has fallen very much below what it was said to
have been when it first fell under the management of the company. The
servants of the company may, perhaps, have profited by the change, but at
the expense, it is probable, both of their masters and of the country.</p>
<p>Taxes upon the Rent of Houses.</p>
<p>The rent of a house may be distinguished into two parts, of which the one
may very properly be called the building-rent; the other is commonly
called the ground-rent.</p>
<p>The building-rent is the interest or profit of the capital expended in
building the house. In order to put the trade of a builder upon a level
with other trades, it is necessary that this rent should be sufficient,
first, to pay him the same interest which he would have got for his
capital, if he had lent it upon good security; and, secondly, to keep the
house in constant repair, or, what comes to the same thing, to replace,
within a certain term of years, the capital which had been employed in
building it. The building-rent, or the ordinary profit of building, is,
therefore, everywhere regulated by the ordinary interest of money. Where
the market rate of interest is four per cent. the rent of a house, which,
over and above paying the ground-rent, affords six or six and a-half per
cent. upon the whole expense of building, may, perhaps, afford a
sufficient profit to the builder. Where the market rate of interest is
five per cent. it may perhaps require seven or seven and a half per cent.
If, in proportion to the interest of money, the trade of the builders
affords at any time much greater profit than this, it will soon draw so
much capital from other trades as will reduce the profit to its proper
level. If it affords at any time much less than this, other trades will
soon draw so much capital from it as will again raise that profit.</p>
<p>Whatever part of the whole rent of a house is over and above what is
sufficient for affording this reasonable profit, naturally goes to the
ground-rent; and, where the owner of the ground and the owner of the
building are two different persons, is, in most cases, completely paid to
the former. This surplus rent is the price which the inhabitant of the
house pays for some real or supposed advantage of the situation. In
country houses, at a distance from any great town, where there is plenty
of ground to chuse upon, the ground-rent is scarce anything, or no more
than what the ground which the house stands upon would pay, if employed in
agriculture. In country villas, in the neighbourhood of some great town,
it is sometimes a good deal higher; and the peculiar conveniency or beauty
of situation is there frequently very well paid for. Ground-rents are
generally highest in the capital, and in those particular parts of it
where there happens to be the greatest demand for houses, whatever be the
reason of that demand, whether for trade and business, for pleasure and
society, or for mere vanity and fashion.</p>
<p>A tax upon house-rent, payable by the tenant, and proportioned to the
whole rent of each house, could not, for any considerable time at least,
affect the building-rent. If the builder did not get his reasonable
profit, he would be obliged to quit the trade; which, by raising the
demand for building, would, in a short time, bring back his profit to its
proper level with that of other trades. Neither would such a tax fall
altogether upon the ground-rent; but it would divide itself in such a
manner, as to fall partly upon the inhabitant of the house, and partly
upon the owner of the ground.</p>
<p>Let us suppose, for example, that a particular person judges that he can
afford for house-rent all expense of sixty pounds a-year; and let us
suppose, too, that a tax of four shillings in the pound, or of one-fifth,
payable by the inhabitant, is laid upon house-rent. A house of sixty
pounds rent will, in that case, cost him seventy-two pounds a-year, which
is twelve pounds more than he thinks he can afford. He will, therefore,
content himself with a worse house, or a house of fifty pounds rent,
which, with the additional ten pounds that he must pay for the tax, will
make up the sum of sixty pounds a-year, the expense which he judges he can
afford, and, in order to pay the tax, he will give up a part of the
additional conveniency which he might have had from a house of ten pounds
a-year more rent. He will give up, I say, a part of this additional
conveniency; for he will seldom be obliged to give up the whole, but will,
in consequence of the tax, get a better house for fifty pounds a-year,
than he could have got if there had been no tax for as a tax of this kind,
by taking away this particular competitor, must diminish the competition
for houses of sixty pounds rent, so it must likewise diminish it for those
of fifty pounds rent, and in the same manner for those of all other rents,
except the lowest rent, for which it would for some time increase the
competition. But the rents of every class of houses for which the
competition was diminished, would necessarily be more or less reduced. As
no part of this reduction, however, could for any considerable time at
least, affect the building-rent, the whole of it must, in the long-run,
necessarily fall upon the ground-rent. The final payment of this tax,
therefore, would fall partly upon the inhabitant of the house, who, in
order to pay his share, would be obliged to give up a part of his
conveniency; and partly upon the owner of the ground, who, in order to pay
his share, would be obliged to give up a part of his revenue. In what
proportion this final payment would be divided between them, it is not,
perhaps, very easy to ascertain. The division would probably be very
different in different circumstances, and a tax of this kind might,
according to those different circumstances, affect very unequally, both
the inhabitant of the house and the owner of the ground.</p>
<p>The inequality with which a tax of this kind might fall upon the owners of
different ground-rents, would arise altogether from the accidental
inequality of this division. But the inequality with which it might fall
upon the inhabitants of different houses, would arise, not only from this,
but from another cause. The proportion of the expense of house-rent to the
whole expense of living, is different in the different degrees of fortune.
It is, perhaps, highest in the highest degree, and it diminishes gradually
through the inferior degrees, so as in general to be lowest in the lowest
degree. The necessaries of life occasion the great expense of the poor.
They find it difficult to get food, and the greater part of their little
revenue is spent in getting it. The luxuries and vanities of life occasion
the principal expense of the rich; and a magnificent house embellishes and
sets off to the best advantage all the other luxuries and vanities which
they possess. A tax upon house-rents, therefore, would in general fall
heaviest upon the rich; and in this sort of inequality there would not,
perhaps, be any thing very unreasonable. It is not very unreasonable that
the rich should contribute to the public expense, not only in proportion
to their revenue, but something more than in that proportion.</p>
<p>The rent of houses, though it in some respects resembles the rent of land,
is in one respect essentially different from it. The rent of land is paid
for the use of a productive subject. The land which pays it produces it.
The rent of houses is paid for the use of an unproductive subject. Neither
the house, nor the ground which it stands upon, produce anything. The
person who pays the rent, therefore, must draw it from some other source
of revenue, distinct from and independent of this subject. A tax upon the
rent of houses, so far as it falls upon the inhabitants, must be drawn
from the same source as the rent itself, and must be paid from their
revenue, whether derived from the wages of labour, the profits of stock,
or the rent of land. So far as it falls upon the inhabitants, it is one of
those taxes which fall, not upon one only, but indifferently upon all the
three different sources of revenue; and is, in every respect, of the same
nature as a tax upon any other sort of consumable commodities. In general,
there is not perhaps, any one article of expense or consumption by which
the liberality or narrowness of a man's whole expense can be better judged
of than by his house-rent. A proportional tax upon this particular article
of expense might, perhaps, produce a more considerable revenue than any
which has hitherto been drawn from it in any part of Europe. If the tax,
indeed, was very high, the greater part of people would endeavour to evade
it as much as they could, by contenting themselves with smaller houses,
and by turning the greater part of their expense into some other channel.</p>
<p>The rent of houses might easily be ascertained with sufficient accuracy,
by a policy of the same kind with that which would be necessary for
ascertaining the ordinary rent of land. Houses not inhabited ought to pay
no tax. A tax upon them would fall altogether upon the proprietor, who
would thus be taxed for a subject which afforded him neither conveniency
nor revenue. Houses inhabited by the proprietor ought to be rated, not
according to the expense which they might have cost in building, but
according to the rent which an equitable arbitration might judge them
likely to bring if leased to a tenant. If rated according to the expense
which they might have cost in building, a tax of three or four shillings
in the pound, joined with other taxes, would ruin almost all the rich and
great families of this, and, I believe, of every other civilized country.
Whoever will examine with attention the different town and country houses
of some of the richest and greatest families in this country, will find
that, at the rate of only six and a-half, or seven per cent. upon the
original expense of building, their house-rent is nearly equal to the
whole neat rent of their estates. It is the accumulated expense of several
successive generations, laid out upon objects of great beauty and
magnificence, indeed, but, in proportion to what they cost, of very small
exchangeable value. {Since the first publication of this book, a tax
nearly upon the above-mentioned principles has been imposed.}</p>
<p>Ground-rents are a still more proper subject of taxation than the rent of
houses. A tax upon ground-rents would not raise the rent of houses; it
would fall altogether upon the owner of the ground-rent, who acts always
as a monopolist, and exacts the greatest rent which can be got for the use
of his ground. More or less can be got for it, according as the
competitors happen to be richer or poorer, or can afford to gratify their
fancy for a particular spot of ground at a greater or smaller expense. In
every country, the greatest number of rich competitors is in the capital,
and it is there accordingly that the highest ground-rents are always to be
found. As the wealth of those competitors would in no respect be increased
by a tax upon ground-rents, they would not probably be disposed to pay
more for the use of the ground. Whether the tax was to be advanced by the
inhabitant or by the owner of the ground, would be of little importance.
The more the inhabitant was obliged to pay for the tax, the less he would
incline to pay for the ground; so that the final payment of the tax would
fall altogether upon the owner of the ground-rent. The ground-rents of
uninhabited houses ought to pay no tax. Both ground-rents, and the
ordinary rent of land, are a species of revenue which the owner, in many
cases, enjoys without any care or attention of his own. Though a part of
this revenue should be taken from him in order to defray the expenses of
the state, no discouragement will thereby be given to any sort of
industry. The annual produce of the land and labour of the society, the
real wealth and revenue of the great body of the people, might be the same
after such a tax as before. Ground-rents, and the ordinary rent of land,
are therefore, perhaps, the species of revenue which can best bear to have
a peculiar tax imposed upon them.</p>
<p>Ground-rents seem, in this respect, a more proper subject of peculiar
taxation, than even the ordinary rent of land. The ordinary rent of land
is, in many cases, owing partly, at least, to the attention and good
management of the landlord. A very heavy tax might discourage, too much,
this attention and good management. Ground-rents, so far as they exceed
the ordinary rent of land, are altogether owing to the good government of
the sovereign, which, by protecting the industry either of the whole
people or of the inhabitants of some particular place, enables them to pay
so much more than its real value for the ground which they build their
houses upon; or to make to its owner so much more than compensation for
the loss which he might sustain by this use of it. Nothing can be more
reasonable, than that a fund, which owes its existence to the good
government of the state, should be taxed peculiarly, or should contribute
something more than the greater part of other funds, towards the support
of that government.</p>
<p>Though, in many different countries of Europe, taxes have been imposed
upon the rent of houses, I do not know of any in which ground-rents have
been considered as a separate subject of taxation. The contrivers of taxes
have, probably, found some difficulty in ascertaining what part of the
rent ought to be considered as ground-rent, and what part ought to be
considered as building-rent. It should not, however, seem very difficult
to distinguish those two parts of the rent from one another.</p>
<p>In Great Britain the rent of houses is supposed to be taxed in the same
proportion as the rent of land, by what is called the annual land tax. The
valuation, according to which each different parish and district is
assessed to this tax, is always the same. It was originally extremely
unequal, and it still continues to be so. Through the greater part of the
kingdom this tax falls still more lightly upon the rent of houses than
upon that of land. In some few districts only, which were originally rated
high, and in which the rents of houses have fallen considerably, the land
tax of three or four shillings in the pound is said to amount to an equal
proportion of the real rent of houses. Untenanted houses, though by law
subject to the tax, are, in most districts, exempted from it by the favour
of the assessors; and this exemption sometimes occasions some little
variation in the rate of particular houses, though that of the district is
always the same. Improvements of rent, by new buildings, repairs, etc. go
to the discharge of the district, which occasions still further variations
in the rate of particular houses.</p>
<p>In the province of Holland, {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. p. 223.}
every house is taxed at two and a-half per cent. of its value, without any
regard, either to the rent which it actually pays, or to the circumstance
of its being tenanted or untenanted. There seems to be a hardship in
obliging the proprietor to pay a tax for an untenanted house, from which
he can derive no revenue, especially so very heavy a tax. In Holland,
where the market rate of interest does not exceed three per cent., two and
a-half per cent. upon the whole value of the house must, in most cases,
amount to more than a third of the building-rent, perhaps of the whole
rent. The valuation, indeed, according to which the houses are rated,
though very unequal, is said to be always below the real value. When a
house is rebuilt, improved, or enlarged, there is a new valuation, and the
tax is rated accordingly.</p>
<p>The contrivers of the several taxes which in England have, at different
times, been imposed upon houses, seem to have imagined that there was some
great difficulty in ascertaining, with tolerable exactness, what was the
real rent of every house. They have regulated their taxes, therefore,
according to some more obvious circumstance, such as they had probably
imagined would, in most cases, bear some proportion to the rent.</p>
<p>The first tax of this kind was hearth-money; or a tax of two shillings
upon every hearth. In order to ascertain how many hearths were in the
house, it was necessary that the tax-gatherer should enter every room in
it. This odious visit rendered the tax odious. Soon after the Revolution,
therefore, it was abolished as a badge of slavery.</p>
<p>The next tax of this kind was a tax of two shillings upon every
dwelling-house inhabited. A house with ten windows to pay four shillings
more. A house with twenty windows and upwards to pay eight shillings. This
tax was afterwards so far altered, that houses with twenty windows, and
with less than thirty, were ordered to pay ten shillings, and those with
thirty windows and upwards to pay twenty shillings. The number of windows
can, in most cases, be counted from the outside, and, in all cases,
without entering every room in the house. The visit of the tax-gatherer,
therefore, was less offensive in this tax than in the hearth-money.</p>
<p>This tax was afterwards repealed, and in the room of it was established
the window-tax, which has undergone two several alterations and
augmentations. The window tax, as it stands at present (January 1775),
over and above the duty of three shillings upon every house in England,
and of one shilling upon every house in Scotland, lays a duty upon every
window, which in England augments gradually from twopence, the lowest rate
upon houses with not more than seven windows, to two shillings, the
highest rate upon houses with twenty-five windows and upwards.</p>
<p>The principal objection to all such taxes is their inequality; an
inequality of the worst kind, as they must frequently fall much heavier
upon the poor than upon the rich. A house of ten pounds rent in a country
town, may sometimes have more windows than a house of five hundred pounds
rent in London; and though the inhabitant of the former is likely to be a
much poorer man than that of the latter, yet, so far as his contribution
is regulated by the window tax, he must contribute more to the support of
the state. Such taxes are, therefore, directly contrary to the first of
the four maxims above mentioned. They do not seem to offend much against
any of the other three.</p>
<p>The natural tendency of the window tax, and of all other taxes upon
houses, is to lower rents. The more a man pays for the tax, the less, it
is evident, he can afford to pay for the rent. Since the imposition of the
window tax, however, the rents of houses have, upon the whole, risen more
or less, in almost every town and village of Great Britain, with which I
am acquainted. Such has been, almost everywhere, the increase of the
demand for houses, that it has raised the rents more than the window tax
could sink them; one of the many proofs of the great prosperity of the
country, and of the increasing revenue of its inhabitants. Had it not been
for the tax, rents would probably have risen still higher.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />