<h2>PART II. Of Taxes.</h2>
<p>The private revenue of individuals, it has been shown in the first book of
this Inquiry, arises, ultimately from three different sources; rent,
profit, and wages. Every tax must finally be paid from some one or other
of those three different sources of revenue, or from all of them
indifferently. I shall endeavour to give the best account I can, first, of
those taxes which, it is intended should fall upon rent; secondly, of
those which, it is intended should fall upon profit; thirdly, of those
which, it is intended should fall upon wages; and fourthly, of those
which, it is intended should fall indifferently upon all those three
different sources of private revenue. The particular consideration of each
of these four different sorts of taxes will divide the second part of the
present chapter into four articles, three of which will require several
other subdivisions. Many of these taxes, it will appear from the following
review, are not finally paid from the fund, or source of revenue, upon
which it is intended they should fall.</p>
<p>Before I enter upon the examination of particular taxes, it is necessary
to premise the four following maximis with regard to taxes in general.</p>
<p>1. The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of
the government, as nearly as possible, in proportion to their respective
abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which they respectively
enjoy under the protection of the state. The expense of government to the
individuals of a great nation, is like the expense of management to the
joint tenants of a great estate, who are all obliged to contribute in
proportion to their respective interests in the estate. In the observation
or neglect of this maxim, consists what is called the equality or
inequality of taxation. Every tax, it must be observed once for all, which
falls finally upon one only of the three sorts of revenue above mentioned,
is necessarily unequal, in so far as it does not affect the other two. In
the following examination of different taxes, I shall seldom take much
farther notice of this sort of inequality; but shall, in most cases,
confine my observations to that inequality which is occasioned by a
particular tax falling unequally upon that particular sort of private
revenue which is affected by it.</p>
<p>2. The tax which each individual is bound to pay, ought to be certain and
not arbitrary. The time of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to
be paid, ought all to be clear and plain to the contributor, and to every
other person. Where it is otherwise, every person subject to the tax is
put more or less in the power of the tax-gatherer, who can either
aggravate the tax upon any obnoxious contributor, or extort, by the terror
of such aggravation, some present or perquisite to himself. The
uncertainty of taxation encourages the insolence, and favours the
corruption, of an order of men who are naturally unpopular, even where
they are neither insolent nor corrupt. The certainty of what each
individual ought to pay is, in taxation, a matter of so great importance,
that a very considerable degree of inequality, it appears, I believe, from
the experience of all nations, is not near so great an evil as a very
small degree of uncertainty.</p>
<p>3. Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in which it
is most likely to be convenient for the contributor to pay it. A tax upon
the rent of land or of houses, payable at the same term at which such
rents are usually paid, is levied at the time when it is most likely to be
convenient for the contributor to pay; or when he is most likely to have
wherewithall to pay. Taxes upon such consumable goods as are articles of
luxury, are all finally paid by the consumer, and generally in a manner
that is very convenient for him. He pays them by little and little, as he
has occasion to buy the goods. As he is at liberty too, either to buy or
not to buy, as he pleases, it must be his own fault if he ever suffers any
considerable inconveniency from such taxes.</p>
<p>4. Every tax ought to be so contrived, as both to take out and to keep out
of the pockets of the people as little as possible, over and above what it
brings into the public treasury of the state. A tax may either take out or
keep out of the pockets of the people a great deal more than it brings
into the public treasury, in the four following ways. First, the levying
of it may require a great number of officers, whose salaries may eat up
the greater part of the produce of the tax, and whose perquisites may
impose another additional tax upon the people. Secondly, it may obstruct
the industry of the people, and discourage them from applying to certain
branches of business which might give maintenance and employment to great
multitudes. While it obliges the people to pay, it may thus diminish, or
perhaps destroy, some of the funds which might enable them more easily to
do so. Thirdly, by the forfeitures and other penalties which those
unfortunate individuals incur, who attempt unsuccessfully to evade the
tax, it may frequently ruin them, and thereby put an end to the benefit
which the community might have received from the employment of their
capitals. An injudicious tax offers a great temptation to smuggling. But
the penalties of smuggling must arise in proportion to the temptation. The
law, contrary to all the ordinary principles of justice, first creates the
temptation, and then punishes those who yield to it; and it commonly
enhances the punishment, too, in proportion to the very circumstance which
ought certainly to alleviate it, the temptation to commit the crime. {See
Sketches of the History of Man page 474, and Seq.} Fourthly, by subjecting
the people to the frequent visits and the odious examination of the
tax-gatherers, it may expose them to much unnecessary trouble, vexation,
and oppression; and though vexation is not, strictly speaking, expense, it
is certainly equivalent to the expense at which every man would be willing
to redeem himself from it. It is in some one or other of these four
different ways, that taxes are frequently so much more burdensome to the
people than they are beneficial to the sovereign.</p>
<p>The evident justice and utility of the foregoing maxims have recommended
them, more or less, to the attention of all nations. All nations have
endeavoured, to the best of their judgment, to render their taxes as equal
as they could contrive; as certain, as convenient to the contributor, both
the time and the mode of payment, and in proportion to the revenue which
they brought to the prince, as little burdensome to the people. The
following short review of some of the principal taxes which have taken
place in different ages and countries, will show, that the endeavours of
all nations have not in this respect been equally successful.</p>
<p>ARTICLE I.—Taxes upon Rent—Taxes upon the Rent of Land.</p>
<p>A tax upon the rent of land may either be imposed according to a certain
canon, every district being valued at a curtain rent, which valuation is
not afterwards to be altered; or it may be imposed in such a manner, as to
vary with every variation in the real rent of the land, and to rise or
fall with the improvement or declension of its cultivation.</p>
<p>A land tax which, like that of Great Britain, is assessed upon each
district according to a certain invariable canon, though it should be
equal at the time of its first establishment, necessarily becomes unequal
in process of time, according to the unequal degrees of improvement or
neglect in the cultivation of the different parts of the country. In
England, the valuation, according to which the different counties and
parishes were assessed to the land tax by the 4th of William and Mary, was
very unequal even at its first establishment. This tax, therefore, so far
offends against the first of the four maxims above mentioned. It is
perfectly agreeable to the other three. It is perfectly certain. The time
of payment for the tax, being the same as that for the rent, is as
convenient as it can be to the contributor. Though the landlord is, in all
cases, the real contributor, the tax is commonly advanced by the tenant,
to whom the landlord is obliged to allow it in the payment of the rent.
This tax is levied by a much smaller number of officers than any other
which affords nearly the same revenue. As the tax upon each district does
not rise with the rise of the rent, the sovereign does not share in the
profits of the landlord's improvements. Those improvements sometimes
contribute, indeed, to the discharge of the other landlords of the
district. But the aggravation of the tax, which this may sometimes
occasion upon a particular estate, is always so very small, that it never
can discourage those improvements, nor keep down the produce of the land
below what it would otherwise rise to. As it has no tendency to diminish
the quantity, it can have none to raise the price of that produce. It does
not obstruct the industry of the people; it subjects the landlord to no
other inconveniency besides the unavoidable one of paying the tax. The
advantage, however, which the land-lord has derived from the invariable
constancy of the valuation, by which all the lands of Great Britain are
rated to the land-tax, has been principally owing to some circumstances
altogether extraneous to the nature of the tax.</p>
<p>It has been owing in part, to the great prosperity of almost every part of
the country, the rents of almost all the estates of Great Britain having,
since the time when this valuation was first established, been continually
rising, and scarce any of them having fallen. The landlords, therefore,
have almost all gained the difference between the tax which they would
have paid, according to the present rent of their estates, and that which
they actually pay according to the ancient valuation. Had the state of the
country been different, had rents been gradually falling in consequence of
the declension of cultivation, the landlords would almost all have lost
this difference. In the state of things which has happened to take place
since the revolution, the constancy of the valuation has been advantageous
to the landlord and hurtful to the sovereign. In a different state of
things it might have been advantageous to the sovereign and hurtful to the
landlord.</p>
<p>As the tax is made payable in money, so the valuation of the land is
expressed in money. Since the establishment of this valuation, the value
of silver has been pretty uniform, and there has been no alteration in the
standard of the coin, either as to weight or fineness. Had silver risen
considerably in its value, as it seems to have done in the course of the
two centuries which preceded the discovery of the mines of America, the
constancy of the valuation might have proved very oppressive to the
landlord. Had silver fallen considerably in its value, as it certainly did
for about a century at least after the discovery of those mines, the same
constancy of valuation would have reduced very much this branch of the
revenue of the sovereign. Had any considerable alteration been made in the
standard of the money, either by sinking the same quantity of silver to a
lower denomination, or by raising it to a higher; had an ounce of silver,
for example, instead of being coined into five shillings and two pence,
been coined either into pieces which bore so low a denomination as two
shillings and seven pence, or into pieces which bore so high a one as ten
shillings and four pence, it would, in the one case, have hurt the revenue
of the proprietor, in the other that of the sovereign.</p>
<p>In circumstances, therefore, somewhat different from those which have
actually taken place, this constancy of valuation might have been a very
great inconveniency, either to the contributors or to the commonwealth. In
the course of ages, such circumstances, however, must at some time or
other happen. But though empires, like all the other works of men, have
all hitherto proved mortal, yet every empire aims at immortality. Every
constitution, therefore, which it is meant should be as permanent as the
empire itself, ought to be convenient, not in certain circumstances only,
but in all circumstances; or ought to be suited, not to those
circumstances which are transitory, occasional, or accidental, but to
those which are necessary, and therefore always the same.</p>
<p>A tax upon the rent of land, which varies with every variation of the
rent, or which rises and falls according to the improvement or neglect of
cultivation, is recommended by that sect of men of letters in France, who
call themselves the economists, as the most equitable of all taxes. All
taxes, they pretend, fall ultimately upon the rent of land, and ought,
therefore, to be imposed equally upon the fund which must finally pay
them. That all taxes ought to fall as equally as possible upon the fund
which must finally pay them, is certainly true. But without entering into
the disagreeable discussion of the metaphysical arguments by which they
support their very ingenious theory, it will sufficiently appear, from the
following review, what are the taxes which fall finally upon the rent of
the land, and what are those which fall finally upon some other fund.</p>
<p>In the Venetian territory, all the arable lands which are given in lease
to farmers are taxed at a tenth of the rent. {Memoires concernant les
Droits, p. 240, 241.} The leases are recorded in a public register, which
is kept by the officers of revenue in each province or district. When the
proprietor cultivates his own lands, they are valued according to an
equitable estimation, and he is allowed a deduction of one-fifth of the
tax; so that for such land he pays only eight instead of ten per cent. of
the supposed rent.</p>
<p>A land-tax of this kind is certainly more equal than the land-tax of
England. It might not, perhaps, be altogether so certain, and the
assessment of the tax might frequently occasion a good deal more trouble
to the landlord. It might, too, be a good deal more expensive in the
levying.</p>
<p>Such a system of administration, however, might, perhaps, be contrived, as
would in a great measure both prevent this uncertainty, and moderate this
expense.</p>
<p>The landlord and tenant, for example, might jointly be obliged to record
their lease in a public register. Proper penalties might be enacted
against concealing or misrepresenting any of the conditions; and if part
of those penalties were to be paid to either of the two parties who
informed against and convicted the other of such concealment or
misrepresentation, it would effectually deter them from combining together
in order to defraud the public revenue. All the conditions of the lease
might be sufficiently known from such a record.</p>
<p>Some landlords, instead of raising the rent, take a fine for the renewal
of the lease. This practice is, in most cases, the expedient of a
spendthrift, who, for a sum of ready money sells a future revenue of much
greater value. It is, in most cases, therefore, hurtful to the landlord;
it is frequently hurtful to the tenant; and it is always hurtful to the
community. It frequently takes from the tenant so great a part of his
capital, and thereby diminishes so much his ability to cultivate the land,
that he finds it more difficult to pay a small rent than it would
otherwise have been to pay a great one. Whatever diminishes his ability to
cultivate, necessarily keeps down, below what it would otherwise have
been, the most important part of the revenue of the community. By
rendering the tax upon such fines a good deal heavier than upon the
ordinary rent, this hurtful practice might be discouraged, to the no small
advantage of all the different parties concerned, of the landlord, of the
tenant, of the sovereign, and of the whole community.</p>
<p>Some leases prescribe to the tenant a certain mode of cultivation, and a
certain succession of crops, during the whole continuance of the lease.
This condition, which is generally the effect of the landlord's conceit of
his own superior knowledge (a conceit in most cases very ill-founded),
ought always to be considered as an additional rent, as a rent in service,
instead of a rent in money. In order to discourage the practice, which is
generally a foolish one, this species of rent might be valued rather high,
and consequently taxed somewhat higher than common money-rents.</p>
<p>Some landlords, instead of a rent in money, require a rent in kind, in
corn, cattle, poultry, wine, oil, etc.; others, again, require a rent in
service. Such rents are always more hurtful to the tenant than beneficial
to the landlord. They either take more, or keep more out of the pocket of
the former, than they put into that of the latter. In every country where
they take place, the tenants are poor and beggarly, pretty much according
to the degree in which they take place. By valuing, in the same manner,
such rents rather high, and consequently taxing them somewhat higher than
common money-rents, a practice which is hurtful to the whole community,
might, perhaps, be sufficiently discouraged.</p>
<p>When the landlord chose to occupy himself a part of his own lands, the
rent might be valued according to an equitable arbitration of the farmers
and landlords in the neighbourhood, and a moderate abatement of the tax
might be granted to him, in the same manner as in the Venetian territory,
provided the rent of the lands which he occupied did not exceed a certain
sum. It is of importance that the landlord should be encouraged to
cultivate a part of his own land. His capital is generally greater than
that of the tenant, and, with less skill, he can frequently raise a
greater produce. The landlord can afford to try experiments, and is
generally disposed to do so. His unsuccessful experiments occasion only a
moderate loss to himself. His successful ones contribute to the
improvement and better cultivation of the whole country. It might be of
importance, however, that the abatement of the tax should encourage him to
cultivate to a certain extent only. If the landlords should, the greater
part of them, be tempted to farm the whole of their own lands, the country
(instead of sober and industrious tenants, who are bound by their own
interest to cultivate as well as their capital and skill will allow them)
would be filled with idle and profligate bailiffs, whose abusive
management would soon degrade the cultivation, and reduce the annual
produce of the land, to the diminution, not only of the revenue of their
masters, but of the most important part of that of the whole society.</p>
<p>Such a system of administration might, perhaps, free a tax of this kind
from any degree of uncertainty, which could occasion either oppression or
inconveniency to the contributor; and might, at the same time, serve to
introduce into the common management of land such a plan of policy as
might contribute a good deal to the general improvement and good
cultivation of the country.</p>
<p>The expense of levying a land-tax, which varied with every variation of
the rent, would, no doubt, be somewhat greater than that of levying one
which was always rated according to a fixed valuation. Some additional
expense would necessarily be incurred, both by the different
register-offices which it would be proper to establish in the different
districts of the country, and by the different valuations which might
occasionally be made of the lands which the proprietor chose to occupy
himself. The expense of all this, however, might be very moderate, and
much below what is incurred in the levying of many other taxes, which
afford a very inconsiderable revenue in comparison of what might easily be
drawn from a tax of this kind.</p>
<p>The discouragement which a variable land-tax of this kind might give to
the improvement of land, seems to be the most important objection which
can be made to it. The landlord would certainly be less disposed to
improve, when the sovereign, who contributed nothing to the expense, was
to share in the profit of the improvement. Even this objection might,
perhaps, be obviated, by allowing the landlord, before he began his
improvement, to ascertain, in conjunction with the officers of revenue,
the actual value of his lands, according to the equitable arbitration of a
certain number of landlords and farmers in the neighbourhood, equally
chosen by both parties: and by rating him, according to this valuation,
for such a number of years as might be fully sufficient for his complete
indemnification. To draw the attention of the sovereign towards the
improvement of the land, from a regard to the increase of his own revenue,
is one or the principal advantages proposed by this species of land-tax.
The term, therefore, allowed, for the indemnification of the landlord,
ought not to be a great deal longer than what was necessary for that
purpose, lest the remoteness of the interest should discourage too much
this attention. It had better, however, be somewhat too long, than in any
respect too short. No incitement to the attention of the sovereign can
ever counterbalance the smallest discouragement to that of the landlord.
The attention of the sovereign can be, at best, but a very general and
vague consideration of what is likely to contribute to the better
cultivation of the greater part of his dominions. The attention of the
landlord is a particular and minute consideration of what is likely to be
the most advantageous application of every inch of ground upon his estate.
The principal attention of the sovereign ought to be, to encourage, by
every means in his power, the attention both of the landlord and of the
farmer, by allowing both to pursue their own interest in their own way,
and according to their own judgment; by giving to both the most perfect
security that they shall enjoy the full recompence of their own industry;
and by procuring to both the most extensive market for every part of their
produce, in consequence of establishing the easiest and safest
communications, both by land and by water, through every part of his own
dominions, as well as the most unbounded freedom of exportation to the
dominions of all other princes.</p>
<p>If, by such a system of administration, a tax of this kind could be so
managed as to give, not only no discouragement, but, on the contrary, some
encouragement to the improvement or land, it does not appear likely to
occasion any other inconveniency to the landlord, except always the
unavoidable one of being obliged to pay the tax. In all the variations of
the state of the society, in the improvement and in the declension of
agriculture; in all the variations in the value of silver, and in all
those in the standard of the coin, a tax of this kind would, of its own
accord, and without any attention of government, readily suit itself to
the actual situation of things, and would be equally just and equitable in
all those different changes. It would, therefore, be much more proper to
be established as a perpetual and unalterable regulation, or as what is
called a fundamental law of the commonwealth, than any tax which was
always to be levied according to a certain valuation.</p>
<p>Some states, instead of the simple and obvious expedient of a register of
leases, have had recourse to the laborious and expensive one of an actual
survey and valuation of all the lands in the country. They have suspected,
probably, that the lessor and lessee, in order to defraud the public
revenue, might combine to conceal the real terms of the lease.
Doomsday-book seems to have been the result of a very accurate survey of
this kind.</p>
<p>In the ancient dominions of the king of Prussia, the land-tax is assessed
according to an actual survey and valuation, which is reviewed and altered
from time to time. {Memoires concurent les Droits, etc. tom, i. p. 114,
115, 116, etc.} According to that valuation, the lay proprietors pay from
twenty to twenty-five per cent. of their revenue; ecclesiastics from forty
to forty-five per cent. The survey and valuation of Silesia was made by
order of the present king, it is said, with great accuracy. According to
that valuation, the lands belonging to the bishop of Breslaw are taxed at
twenty-five per cent. of their rent. The other revenues of the
ecclesiastics of both religions at fifty per cent. The commanderies of the
Teutonic order, and of that of Malta, at forty per cent. Lands held by a
noble tenure, at thirty-eight and one-third per cent. Lands held by a base
tenure, at thirty-five and one-third per cent.</p>
<p>The survey and valuation of Bohemia is said to have been the work of more
than a hundred years. It was not perfected till after the peace of 1748,
by the orders of the present empress queen. {Id. tom i. p.85, 84.} The
survey of the duchy of Milan, which was begun in the time of Charles VI.,
was not perfected till after 1760 It is esteemed one of the most accurate
that has ever been made. The survey of Savoy and Piedmont was executed
under the orders of the late king of Sardinia. {Id. p. 280, etc.; also p,
287. etc. to 316.}</p>
<p>In the dominions of the king of Prussia, the revenue of the church is
taxed much higher than that of lay proprietors. The revenue of the church
is, the greater part of it, a burden upon the rent of land. It seldom
happens that any part of it is applied towards the improvement of land; or
is so employed as to contribute, in any respect, towards increasing the
revenue of the great body of the people. His Prussian majesty had
probably, upon that account, thought it reasonable that it should
contribute a good deal more towards relieving the exigencies of the state.
In some countries, the lands of the church are exempted from all taxes. In
others, they are taxed more lightly than other lands. In the duchy of
Milan, the lands which the church possessed before 1575, are rated to the
tax at a third only or their value.</p>
<p>In Silesia, lands held by a noble tenure are taxed three per cent. higher
than those held by a base tenure. The honours and privileges of different
kinds annexed to the former, his Prussian majesty had probably imagined,
would sufficiently compensate to the proprietor a small aggravation of the
tax; while, at the same time, the humiliating inferiority of the latter
would be in some measure alleviated, by being taxed somewhat more lightly.
In other countries, the system of taxation, instead of alleviating,
aggravates this inequality. In the dominions of the king of Sardinia, and
in those provinces of France which are subject to what is called the real
or predial taille, the tax falls altogether upon the lands held by a base
tenure. Those held by a noble one are exempted.</p>
<p>A land tax assessed according to a general survey and valuation, how equal
soever it may be at first, must, in the course of a very moderate period
of time, become unequal. To prevent its becoming so would require the
continual and painful attention of government to all the variations in the
state and produce of every different farm in the country. The governments
of Prussia, of Bohemia, of Sardinia, and of the duchy of Milan, actually
exert an attention of this kind; an attention so unsuitable to the nature
of government, that it is not likely to be of long continuance, and which,
if it is continued, will probably, in the long-run, occasion much more
trouble and vexation than it can possibly bring relief to the
contributors.</p>
<p>In 1666, the generality of Montauban was assessed to the real or predial
taille, according, it is said, to a very exact survey and valuation.
{Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. ii p. 139, etc.} By 1727, this
assessment had become altogether unequal. In order to remedy this
inconveniency, government has found no better expedient, than to impose
upon the whole generality an additional tax of a hundred and twenty
thousand livres. This additional tax is rated upon all the different
districts subject to the taille according to the old assessment. But it is
levied only upon those which, in the actual state of things, are by that
assessment under-taxed; and it is applied to the relief of those which, by
the same assessment, are over-taxed. Two districts, for example, one of
which ought, in the actual state of things, to be taxed at nine hundred,
the other at eleven hundred livres, are, by the old assessment, both taxed
at a thousand livres. Both these districts are, by the additional tax,
rated at eleven hundred livres each. But this additional tax is levied
only upon the district under-charged, and it is applied altogether to the
relief of that overcharged, which consequently pays only nine hundred
livres. The government neither gains nor loses by the additional tax,
which is applied altogether to remedy the inequalities arising from the
old assessment. The application is pretty much regulated according to the
discretion of the intendant of the generality, and must, therefore, be in
a great measure arbitrary.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />